READING HALLDOORS OF WISDOM |
GREECE UNDER THE ROMANS. B.C. 146 — A.D. 716
CHAPTER I.
From the Conquest of Greece to the Establishment of Constantinople as
Capital of the Roman Empire. B.C. 146 — A.D. 330
The conquests of Alexander the Great effected a permanent change in the
political condition of the Greek nation, and this change powerfully influenced
its moral and social state during the whole period of its subjection to the
Roman empire. The international system of policy by which Alexander connected
Greece with Western Asia and Egypt, was only effaced by the religion of Mahomet
and the conquests of the Arabs. Though Alexander was himself a Greek, both from
education, and the prejudices cherished by the pride of ancestry, still neither
the people of Macedonia, nor the chief part of the army, whose discipline and
valour had secured his victories, was Greek, either in language or feelings.
Had Alexander, therefore, determined on organizing his empire with the view of
uniting the Macedonians and Persians in common feelings of opposition to the
Greek nation, there can be no doubt that he could easily have accomplished the
design. The Greeks might then have found themselves enabled to adopt a very
different course in their national career from that which they were compelled
to follow by the powerful influence exercised over them by Alexander’s conduct.
Alexander himself, undoubtedly, perceived that the greater numbers of the
Persians, and their equality, if not superiority, in civilization to the
Macedonians, rendered it necessary for him to seek some powerful ally to
prevent the absorption of the Macedonians in the Persian population, the loss of
their language, manners, and nationality, and the speedy change of his empire
into the sovereignty of a mere Graeco-Persian dynasty. It did not escape his
discernment, that the political institutions of the Greeks created a principle
of nationality capable of combating the unalterable laws of the Medes and
Persians.
Alexander was the noblest model of a conqueror; his ambition aspired at
eclipsing the glory of his unparalleled victories by the universal prosperity
which was to flow from his civil government. New cities and extended commerce
were to found an era in the world’s history. Even the strength of his empire
was to be based on a political principle which he has the merit of discovering,
and of which he proved the efficacy; this principle was the amalgamation of his
subjects into one people by permanent institutions. All other conquerors have
endeavoured to augment their power by the subjection of one race to another.
The merit of Alexander is very much increased by the nature of his position
with regard to the Greek nation. The Greeks were not favourably disposed either
towards his empire or his person; they would willingly have destroyed both as
the surest way of securing their own liberty. But the moral energy of the Greek
national character did not escape the observation of Alexander, and he resolved
to render this quality available for the preservation of his empire, by
introducing into the East those municipal institutions which gave it vigour,
and thus facilitate the infusion of some portion of the Hellenic character into
the hearts of his conquered subjects.
The moderation of Alexander in the execution of his plans of reform and
change is as remarkable as the wisdom of his extensive projects. In order to
mould the Asiatics to his wishes, he did not attempt to enforce laws and
constitutions similar to those of Greece. He profited too well by the lessons
of Aristotle to think of treating man as a machine. But he introduced Greek
civilization as an important element in his civil government, and established
Greek colonies with political rights throughout his conquests. It is true that
he seized all the unlimited power of the Persian monarchs, but, at the same
time, he strove to secure administrative responsibility, and to establish free
institutions in municipal government. Any laws or constitution which Alexander
could have promulgated to enforce his system of consolidating the population of
his empire into one body, would most probably have been immediately repealed by
his successors, in consequence of the hostile feelings of the Macedonian army.
But it was more difficult to escape from the tendency imprinted on the
administration by the systematic arrangements which Alexander had introduced.
He seems to have been fully aware of this fact, though it is impossible to
trace the whole series of measures he adopted to accelerate the completion of
his great project of creating a new state of society, and a new nation, as well
as a new empire, in the imperfect records of his civil administration which have
survived. His death left his own scheme incomplete, yet his success was
wonderful; for though his empire was immediately dismembered, its numerous
portions long retained a deep imprint of that Greek civilization which he had
introduced. The influence of his philanthropic policy survived the kingdoms
which his arms had founded, and tempered the despotic sway of the Romans by its
superior power over society; nor was the influence of Alexander’s government
utterly effaced in Asia until Mahomet changed the government, the religion, and
the frame of society in the East.
The monarchs of Egypt, Syria, Pergamus, and Bactriana, who were either
Macedonians or Greeks, respected the civil institutions, the language, and the
religion of their native subjects, however adverse they might be to Greek
usages; and the sovereigns of Bithynia, Pontus, Cappadocia, and Parthia, though
native princes, retained a deep tincture of Greek civilization after they had
thrown off the Macedonian yoke. They not only encouraged the arts, sciences,
and literature of Greece, but they even protected the peculiar political
constitutions of the Greek colonies settled in their dominions, though at
variance with the Asiatic views of monarchical government.
The Greeks and Macedonians long continued separate nations, though a number
of the causes which ultimately produced their fusion began to exert some
influence shortly after the death of Alexander. The moral and social causes
which enabled the Greeks to acquire a complete superiority over the Macedonian
race, and ultimately to absorb it as a component element of their own nation,
were the same which afterwards enabled them to destroy the Roman influence in
the East. For several generations, the Greeks appeared the feebler party in
their struggle with the Macedonians. The new kingdoms, into which Alexander’s
empire was divided, were placed in very different circumstances from the older
Greek states. Two separate divisions were created in the Hellenic world, and
the Macedonian monarchies on the one hand, and the free Greeks on the other,
formed two distinct international systems of policy. The Macedonian sovereigns
had a balance of power to maintain, in which the free states of Europe could
only be directly interested when the overwhelming influence of a conqueror
placed their independence in jeopardy. The multifarious diplomatic relations of
the free states among themselves required constant attention, not only to
maintain their political independence, but even to protect their property and
civil rights. These two great divisions of Hellenic society were often governed
by opposite views and feelings in morals and politics, though their various
members were continually placed in alliance as well as collision by their
struggles to preserve the balance of power of their respective systems.
The immense power and wealth of the Seleucidae and Ptolemies rendered vain
all the efforts of the small European states to maintain the high military,
civil, and literary rank they had previously occupied. Their best soldiers,
their wisest statesmen, and their ablest authors, were induced to emigrate to a
more profitable and extensive scene of action. Alexandria became the capital of
the Hellenic world. Yet the history of the European states still continued to
maintain its predominant interest, and as a political lesson, the struggles of
the Achaian. League to defend the independence of Greece against Macedonia and
Rome, are not less instructive than the annals of Athens and Sparta. The
European Greeks at this period perceived all the danger to which their
liberties were exposed from the wealth, and power of the Asiatic monarchies,
and they vainly endeavoured to effect a combination of all the free states into
one federal body. Whatever might have been the success of such a combination,
it certainly offered the only hope of preserving the liberty of Greece against
the powerful states with which the altered condition of the civilized world had
brought her into contact.
At the very time when the Macedonian kings were attacking the independence
of Greece, and the Asiatic courts undermining the morals of the Greek nation,
the Greek colonies, whose independence, from their remote situation, was
secured against the attacks of the Eastern monarchs, were conquered by the
Romans. Many circumstances tending to weaken the Greeks, and over which they
had no control, followed one another with fatal celerity. The invasion of the
Gauls, though bravely repulsed, inflicted great losses on Greece. Shortly
after, the Romans completed the conquest of the Greek states in Italy. From
that time the Sicilian Greeks were too feeble to be anything but spectators of
the fierce struggle of the Romans and Carthaginians for the sovereignty of
their island, and though the city of Syracuse courageously defended its
independence, the struggle was a hopeless tribute to national glory. The cities
of Cyrenaica had been long subject to the Ptolemies, and the republics on the
shores of the Black Sea had been unable to maintain their liberties against the
repeated attacks of the sovereigns of Pontus and Bithynia.
Though the Macedonians and Greeks were separated into two divisions by the
opposite interests of the Asiatic monarchies and the European republics, still
they were united by a powerful bond of national feelings. There was a strong
similarity in the education, religion, and social position of the individual
citizen in every state, whether Greek or Macedonian. Wherever Hellenic
civilization was received, the free citizens formed only one part of the
population, whether the other was composed of slaves or subjects; and this
peculiarity placed their civil interests as Greeks in a more important light
than their political differences as subjects of various states. The Macedonian
Greeks of Asia and Egypt were a ruling class, governed, it is true, by an
absolute sovereign, but having their interest so identified with his, in the
vital question of retaining the administration of the country, that the Greeks,
even in the absolute monarchies, formed a favoured and privileged class. In the
Greek republics, the case was not very dissimilar; there, too, a small body of
free citizens ruled a large slave or subject population, whose numbers required
not only constant attention on the part of the rulers, but likewise a deep
conviction of an ineffaceable separation in interests and character, to
preserve the ascendency. This peculiarity in the position of the Greeks
cherished their exclusive nationality, and created a feeling that the laws of
honour and of nations forbade free men ever to make common cause with slaves.
The influence of this feeling was visible for centuries on the laws and
education of the free citizens of Greece, and it was equally powerful wherever
Hellenic civilization spread.
Alexander’s conquests soon exercised a widely extended influence on the
commerce, literature, morals, and religion of the Greeks. A direct
communication was opened with India, with the centre of Asia, and with the
southern coast of Africa. This immense extension of the commercial transactions
of the Asiatic and Egyptian Greeks diminished the relative wealth and
importance of the European states, while, at the same time, their stationary
position assumed the aspect of decline from the rapidly increasing power and
civilization of Western Europe. A considerable trade began to be carried on
directly with the great commercial depots of the East which had formerly
afforded large profits to the Greeks of Europe by passing through their hands.
As soon as Rome rose to some degree of power, its inhabitants, if not its
franchised citizens, traded with the East, as is proved by the existence of
political relations between Rome and Rhodes, more than three centuries before
the Christian era. There can be no doubt that the connection between the two
states had its origin in the interests of trade. New channels were opened for
mercantile enterprise as direct communications diminished the expense of
transport. The increase of trade rendered piracy a profitable occupation. Both
the sovereigns of Egypt and the merchants of Rhodes favoured the pirates who
plundered the Syrians and Phoenicians, so that trading vessels could only
navigate with safety under the protection of powerful states, in order to
secure their property from extortion and plunder, These alterations in
commercial affairs proved every way disadvantageous to the small republics of
European Greece; and Alexandria and Rhodes soon occupied the position once held
by Corinth and Athens.
The literature of a people is so intimately connected with the local
circumstances which influence education, taste, and morals, that it can never
be transplanted without undergoing a great alteration. It is not wonderful,
therefore, that the literature of the Greeks, after the extension of their
dominion in the East, should have undergone a great change; but it seems
remarkable that this change should have proved invariably injurious to all its
peculiar excellencies. It is singular, at the same time, to find how little the
Greeks occupied themselves in the examination of the stores of knowledge
possessed by the Eastern nations. The situation and interests of the Asiatic
and Egyptian Greeks must have compelled many to learn the languages of the
countries which they inhabited, and the literature of the East was laid open to
their investigation. They appear to have availed themselves very sparingly of
these advantages. Even in history and geography, they made but small additions
to the information already collected by Herodotus, Ctesias, and Xenophon; and
this supercilious neglect of foreign literature has been the cause of depriving
modern times of all records of the powerful and civilized nations which
flourished while Greece was in a state of barbarism. Had the Macedonians or
Romans treated the history and literature of Greece with the contempt which the
Greeks showed to the records of the Phoenicians, Persians, and Egyptians, it is
not probable that any very extensive remains of later Greek literature would
have reached us. At a subsequent period, when the Arabs had conquered the
Syrian and Egyptian Greeks, their neglect of the language and literature of
Greece was severely felt.
The munificence of the Ptolemies, the Seleucidae, and the kings of
Pergamus, enabled their capitals to eclipse the literary glory of the cities of
Greece. The eminent men of Europe sought their fortunes abroad; but when genius
emigrated it could not transplant those circumstances which created and
sustained it. In Egypt and in Syria, Greek literature lost its national
character; and that divine instinct in the portraiture of nature, which had
been the charm of its earlier age, never emigrated. This deficiency forms,
indeed, the marked distinction between the literature of the Grecian and
Macedonian periods; and it was a natural consequence of the different
situations held by literary men. Among the Asiatic and Alexandrine population,
literature was a trade, knowledge was confined to the higher classes, and
literary productions were addressed to a public widely dispersed and dissimilar
in many tastes and habits. The authors who addressed themselves to such a
public could not escape a vagueness of expression on some subjects, and an
affectation of occult profundity on others. Learning and science, in so far as they
could be rendered available for upholding literary renown, were most studiously
cultivated, and most successfully employed; but deep feeling, warm enthusiasm,
and simple truth were, from the very nature of the case, impossible.
The frame of society in earlier times had been very different in the free
states of Greece. Literature and the fine arts then formed a portion of the
usual education and ordinary life of every citizen in the State; they were
consequently completely under the influence of public opinion, and received the
impress of the national mind which they reflected from the mirror of genius.
The effects of this popular character in Greek literature and art are evident,
in the total freedom of all the productions of Greece, in her best days, from
anything that partakes of mannerism or exaggeration. The truer to nature any
production could be rendered, which was to be offered to the attention of the
people, the abler would they be to appreciate its merits, and their applause
would be obtained with greater certainty; yet, at the same time, the farther
the expression of nature could be removed from vulgarity, the higher would be
the degree of general admiration. The sentiment necessary for the realization
of ideal perfection, which modern civilization vainly requires from those who
labour only for the polished and artificial classes of a society broken into
sections, arose in profusion, under the free instinct of the popular mind to
reverence simplicity and nature, when combined with beauty and dignity.
The connection of the Greeks with Assyria and Egypt, nevertheless, aided
their progress in mathematics and scientific knowledge; yet astrology was the
only new object of science which their Eastern studies added to the domain of
the human intellect. From the time Berosus introduced astrology into Cos, it
spread with inconceivable rapidity in Europe. It soon exercised a powerful
influence over the religious opinions of the higher classes, naturally inclined
to fatalism, and assisted in demoralizing the private and public character of
the Greeks. From the Greeks it spread with additional empiricism among the
Romans: it even maintained its ground against Christianity, with which it long
strove to form an alliance, and it has only been extirpated in modern times.
The Romans, as long as they clung to their national usages and religious
feelings, endeavoured to resist the progress of a study so destructive to
private and public virtue; but it embodied opinions which were rapidly gaining
ground. In the time of the Caesars, astrology was generally believed, and
extensively practised.
The general corruption of morals which followed from the Macedonian
conquests, was the inevitable effect of the position in which mankind were
everywhere placed. The accumulated treasures of the Persian Empire, which must
have amounted to between seventy and eighty millions sterling, were suddenly
thrown into general circulation, and the large sums which passed into the hands
of the soldiery enriched the very worst classes of society. The Greeks profited
greatly by the expenditure of these treasures, and their social position became
soon so completely changed by the facilities afforded them of gaining high pay,
and of enjoying luxury in the service of foreign princes, that public opinion
ceased to exercise a direct influence on private character . The mixture of
Macedonians, Greeks, and natives, in the conquered countries of the East, was
very incomplete, and they generally formed distinct classes of society: this
circumstance alone contributed to weaken the feelings of moral responsibility,
which are the most powerful preservatives of virtue. It is difficult to imagine
a state of society more completely destitute of moral restraint than that in
which the Asiatic Greeks lived. Public opinion was powerless to enforce even an
outward respect for virtue; military accomplishments, talents for civil
administration, literary eminence, and devotion to the power of an arbitrary
sovereign, were the direct roads to distinction and wealth; honesty and virtue
were very secondary qualities. In all countries or societies where a class
becomes predominant, a conventional character is formed, according to the
exigencies of the case, as the standard of an honourable man; and it is usually
very different indeed from what is really necessary to constitute a virtuous,
or even an honest citizen.
With regard to the European Greeks, high rank at the Asiatic courts was
often suddenly, and indeed accidentally, placed within their reach by qualities
that had in general only been cultivated as a means of obtaining a livelihood.
It is not, therefore, wonderful that wealth and power, obtained under such
circumstances, should have been wasted in luxury, and squandered in the
gratification of lawless passions. Yet, in spite of the complaints most justly
recorded in history against the luxury, idleness, avarice, and debauchery of
the Greeks, it seems surprising that the people resisted, so effectually as it
did, the powerful means at work to accomplish the national ruin. There never
existed a people more perfectly at liberty to gratify every passion. During two
hundred and fifty years, the Greeks were the dominant class in Asia; and the
corrupting influence of this predominance was extended to the whole frame of
society, in their European as well as their Asiatic possessions. The history of
the Achaian League, and the endeavours of Agis and Cleomenes to restore the
ancient institutions of Sparta, prove that public and private virtue were still
admired and appreciated by the native Greeks. The Romans, who were the loudest
in condemning and satirizing the vices of the nation, proved far less able to
resist the allurements of wealth and power; and in the course of one century,
their demoralization far exceeded the corruption of the Greeks. The severe tone
in which Polybius animadverts on the vices of his countrymen, must always be
contrasted with the picture of Roman depravity in the pages of Suetonius and
Tacitus, in order to form a correct estimate of the moral position of the two
nations. The Greeks afford a sad spectacle of the debasing influence of wealth
and power on the higher classes; but the Romans, after their Asiatic conquests,
present the loathsome picture of a whole people throwing aside all moral
restraint, and openly wallowing in those vices which the higher classes
elsewhere have generally striven to conceal.
The religion of the Greeks was little more than a section of the political
constitution of the State. The power of religion depended on custom. Strictly
speaking, therefore, the Greeks never possessed anything more than a national
form of worship, and their religious feelings produced no very important
influence on their moral conduct. The conquests of Alexander effected as great
a change in religion as in manners. The Greeks willingly adopted the
superstitious practices of the conquered nations, and, without hesitation, paid
their devotions at the shrines of foreign divinities; but, strange to say, they
never appear to have profoundly investigated either the metaphysical opinions
or the religious doctrines of the Eastern nations. They treated with neglect
the pure theism of Moses, and the sublime religious system of Zoroaster, while
they cultivated a knowledge of the astrology, necromancy, and sorcery of the Chaldaeans,
Syrians, and Egyptians.
The separation of the higher and lower ranks of society, which only
commenced among the Greeks after their Asiatic conquests, produced a marked
effect on the religious ideas of the nation. Among the wealthy and the learned,
indifference to all religions rapidly gained ground. The philosophical
speculations of Alexander’s age tended towards scepticism; and the state of
mankind, in the following century, afforded practical proofs to the ancients of
the insufficiency of virtue and reason to insure happiness and success either
in public or private life. The consequence was, that the greater number
embraced the belief in a blind overruling destiny, — while a few became
atheists. The absurdities of popular paganism had been exposed and ridiculed,
while its mythology had not yet been explained by philosophical allegories. No
system of philosophy, on the other hand, had sought to enforce its moral truths
among the people, by declaring the principle of man's responsibility. The lower
orders were without philosophy, the higher without religion.
This separation in the feelings and opinions of the different ranks of
society, rendered the value of public opinion comparatively insignificant to
the philosophers; and consequently, their doctrines were no longer addressed to
the popular mind. The education of the lower orders, which had always depended
on the public lessons they had received from voluntary teachers in the public
places of resort, was henceforward neglected; and the priests of the temples,
the diviners and soothsayers, became their instructors and guides. Under such
guidance, the old mythological fables, and the new wonders of the Eastern
magicians, were employed as the surest means of rendering the superstitious
feelings of the people, and the popular dread of supernatural influences, a
source of profit to the priesthood. While the educated became the votaries of
Chaldaeans and astrologers, the ignorant were the admirers of Egyptians and
conjurors.
The Greek nation, immediately before the conquest of the Romans, was rich
both in wealth and numbers. Alexander had thrown the accumulated treasures of
centuries into circulation; the dismemberment of his empire prevented his
successors from draining the various countries of the world, to expend their
resources on a single city. The number of capitals and independent cities in
the Grecian world kept money in circulation, enabled trade to flourish, and
caused the Greek population to increase. The elements of national prosperity
are so various and complex, that a knowledge of the numbers of a people affords
no certain criterion for estimating their wealth and happiness; still, if it
were possible to obtain accurate accounts of the population of all the
countries inhabited by the Greeks after the death of Alexander, such knowledge
would afford better means of estimating the real progress or decline of social
civilization, than either the records which history has preserved of the
results of wars and negotiations, or than the memorials of art and literature.
The population of Greece, as of every other country, must have varied very much
at different periods; even the proportion of the slave to the free inhabitants
can never have long remained exactly the same. We are, unfortunately, so completely
ignorant of the relative density of the Greek population at different periods,
and so well assured that its absolute numbers depended on many causes which it
is now impossible to appreciate fully, that it would be a vain endeavour to
attempt to fix the period when the Greek race was most numerous. The empire of
the Greeks was most extensive during the century which elapsed immediately
after the death of Alexander; but it would be unsafe to draw, from that single
fact, any certain conclusion concerning the numbers of the Greek race at that
period, as compared with the following century.
The fallacy of any inferences concerning the population of ancient times,
which are drawn from the numbers of the inhabitants in modern times, is
apparent, when we reflect on the rapid increase of mankind, in the greater part
of Europe, in late years. Gibbon estimates the population of the Roman Empire,
in the time of Claudius, at one hundred and twenty millions, and he supposed
modern Europe to contain, at the time he wrote, one hundred and seven millions.
Seventy years have not elapsed, and yet the countries which he enumerated now
contain upwards of two hundred and ten millions. The variations which have
taken place in the numbers of the Jews at different periods, illustrate the
vicissitudes to which an expatriated population, like a large portion of the
Greek nation, is always liable. The Jews have often been far less — perhaps
they have been frequently more numerous — than they are at present, yet their
numbers now seem to equal what they were at the era of the greatest wealth,
power, and glory of their nation under Solomon. A very judicious writer has
estimated the population of continental Greece, Peloponnesus, and the Ionian
Islands, at three millions and a half, during the period which elapsed from the
Persian wars to the death of Alexander. Now, if we admit a similar density of
population in Crete, Cyprus, the islands of the Archipelago, and the colonies
on the coasts of Thrace and Asia Minor, this number would require to be more
than doubled. The population of European Greece declined after the time of
Alexander. Money became more abundant; it was easy for a Greek to make his
fortune abroad; increased wealth augmented the wants of the free citizens, and
the smaller states became incapable of supporting as large a free population as
in earlier times, when wants were fewer, and emigration difficult. The size of
properties and the number of slaves, therefore, increased. The diminution which
had taken place in the population of Greece must, however, have been trifling,
when compared with the immense increase in the Greek population of Asia and
Egypt; in Magna Graecia, Sicily, and Cyrene, the number of the Greeks had not
decreased. Greek civilization had extended itself from the banks of the Indus
to the Pillars of Hercules, and from the shores of the Palus Maeotis to the
island of Dioscorides. It may therefore be admitted, that the Greeks were, at
no earlier period of their history, more numerous than at the time the Romans
commenced the subjugation of the countries which they inhabited.
The history of the Greeks under the Roman domination tends to correct the
opinion that national changes are to be solely attributed to those remarkable
occurrences which occupy the most prominent place in the annals of states. It
not unfrequently happened that those events which produced the greatest change
on the fortunes of the Romans, exerted no very important or permanent influence
on the fate of the Greeks ; while, on the other hand, some change in the state
of India, Bactria, Ethiopia, or Arabia, by altering the direction of commerce,
powerfully influenced their prosperity and future destinies. A revolution in
the commercial intercourse between Europe and eastern Asia, which threw ancient
Greece out of the direct line of trade, assisted in producing the great changes
which took place in the Greek nation, from the period of the subjection of
Greece by the Romans, to that of the conquest of the semi-Greek provinces which
had belonged to the Macedonian empire, by the Saracens. The history of mankind
requires a more accurate illustration than has yet been undertaken, of the
causes of the depopulation and impoverishment of the people, as well as of the
general degradation of all the political governments with which we are
acquainted, during the period embraced in this volume; but the task belongs to
universal history. To obtain a correct view of the social condition of the
European nations in the darkest periods of the middle ages, it is necessary to
examine society through a Greek as well as a Roman medium, and to weigh the
experience and the passions of the East against the force and the prejudices of
the West. It will then be found, that many germs of that civilization which
seemed to have arisen in the dark ages as a natural development of society,
were really borrowed from the Greek people and the Byzantine empire, in which a
Graeco-Macedonian civilization long pervaded society.
Sect. I
Immediate causes of the Conquest of
Greece by the Romans
The great difference which existed in the social condition of the Greeks
and Romans during the whole of their national existence, must be kept in view,
in order to form a just idea of their relative position when ruled by the same
government. The Romans formed a nation with the organization of a single city;
their political government, always partaking of its municipal origin, was a
type of concentration in administrative power, and was enabled to pursue its objects
with undeviating steadiness of purpose. The Greeks were a people composed of a
number of rival states, whose attention was incessantly diverted to various
objects. The great end of existence among the Romans was war; they were the
children of Mars, and they reverenced their progenitor with the most fervent
enthusiasm. Agriculture itself was only honoured from necessity. Among the
Greeks, civil virtues were called into action by the multifarious exigencies of
society, and were honoured and deified by the nation. Linked together by an
international system of independent states, the Greeks regarded war as a means
of obtaining some definite object, in accordance with the established balance
of power. A state of peace was, in their view, the natural state of mankind.
The Romans regarded war as their permanent occupation; their national and
individual ambition was exclusively directed to conquest. The subjection of
their enemies, or a perpetual struggle for supremacy, was the only alternative
that war presented to their minds.
The success of the Roman arms and the conquest of Greece were the natural
results of concentrated national feelings, and superior military organization,
contending with an ill-cemented political league, and an inferior military
system. The Roman was instructed to regard himself merely as a component part
of the republic, and to view Rome as placed in opposition to the rest of
mankind. The Greek, though he possessed the moral feeling of nationality quite
as powerfully as the Roman, could not concentrate equal political energy. The
Greeks after the period of the Macedonian conquests, occupied the double
position of members of a widely-spread and dominant people, and of citizens of
independent states. Their minds were enlarged by this extension of their sphere
of civilization; but what they gained in general feelings of philanthropy, they
appear to have lost in patriotic attachment to the interest of their native
states.
It would be a vain exercise of ingenuity to speculate on the course of
events, and on the progress of the ancient world, had the national spirit of
Greece been awakened in her struggle with Rome, and the war between the two
peoples involved the question of Greek nationality, as well as political
independence. On the one hand, Greece and Rome might be supposed existing as
rival states, mutually aiding the progress of mankind by their emulation; on
the other, the extinction of the Greek people, as well as the destruction of
their political government, might be regarded as a not improbable event. No
strong national feeling was, however, raised in Greece by the wars with Rome,
and the contest remained only a political one in the eyes of the people;
consequently, even if the military power of the belligerents had been more
nearly balanced than it really was, the struggle could hardly have terminated
in any other way than by the subjugation of the Greeks.
It seems at first sight more difficult to explain the facility with which
the Greeks accommodated themselves to the Roman sway, and the rapidity with
which they sank into political insignificancy, than the ease with which they
were vanquished in the field. The fact, however, is undeniable, that the
conquest was generally viewed with satisfaction by the great body of the
inhabitants of Greece, who considered the destruction of the numerous small
independent governments in the country as a necessary step towards improving
their own condition. The political constitutions even of the most democratic
states of Greece excluded so large a portion of the inhabitants from all share
in the public administration, and after the introduction of large mercenary
armies, military service became so severe a burden on the free citizens, that
the majority looked with indifference on the loss of their independence, when
that loss appeared to insure a permanent state of peace. The selfishness of the
Greek aristocracy, which was prominently displayed at every period of history,
proved peculiarly injurious in the latter days of Greek independence. The aristocracy
of the Greek cities and states indulged their ambition and cupidity to the ruin
of their country. The selfishness of the Roman aristocracy was possibly as
great, but it was very different. It found gratification in increasing the
power and glory of Rome, and it identified itself with pride and patriotism;
Greek selfishness, on the contrary, submitted to every meanness from which an
aristocracy usually recoils; and to gratify its passions, it sacrificed its
country. Greece had arrived at that period of civilization, when political
questions were determined by financial reasons, and the hope of a diminution of
the public burdens was a powerful argument in favour of submission to Rome.
When the Romans conquered Macedonia, they fixed the tribute at one half the
amount which had been paid to the Macedonian kings.
At the period of the Roman conquest, public opinion had been vitiated, as
well as weakened, by the corrupt influence of the Asiatic monarchies. Many of
the Greek princes employed large sums in purchasing the military services and
civic flatteries of the free states. The political and military leaders
throughout Greece were thus, by means of foreign alliances, rendered masters of
resources far beyond what the unassisted revenues of the free states could have
placed at their disposal. It soon became evident that the fate of many of the
free states depended on their alliances with the kings of Macedonia, Egypt,
Syria, and Pergamus; and the citizens could not avoid the despairing conclusion
that no exertion on their part could produce any decisive effect in securing
the tranquillity of Greece. They could only increase their own taxes, and bring
to their own homes all the miseries of a most inhuman system of warfare. This
state of public affairs caused the despair which induced the Acarnanians and
the citizens of Abydos to adopt the heroic resolution not to survive the loss
of their independence; but its more general effect was to spread public and
private demoralization through all ranks of society. Peace alone, to the
reflecting Greeks, seemed capable of restoring security of property, and of
re-establishing due respect for the principles of justice; and peace seemed
only attainable by submission to the Romans. The continuation of a state of
war, which was rapidly laying the fortified towns in ruin, and consuming the
resources of the land, was regarded by the independent Greeks as a far greater
evil than Roman supremacy. So ardently was the termination of the contest
desired, that a common proverb, expressive of a wish that the Romans might
speedily prevail, was everywhere current. This saying, which was common after
the conquest, has been preserved by Polybius: “If we had not been quickly
ruined, we should not have been saved”.
It was some time before the Greeks had great reason to regret their
fortune. A combination of causes, which could hardly have entered into the
calculations of any politician, enabled them to preserve their national
institutions, and to exercise all their former social influence, even after the
annihilation of their political existence. Their vanity was flattered by their
admitted superiority in arts and literature, and by the respect paid to their
usages and prejudices by the Romans. Their political subjection was at first
not very burdensome; and a considerable portion of the nation was allowed to
retain the appearance of independence. Athens and Sparta were honoured with the
title of allies of Rome. The nationality of the Greeks was so interwoven with
their municipal institutions, that the Romans found it impossible to abolish
the local administration; and an imperfect attempt, made at the time of the
conquest of Achaia, was soon abandoned. These local institutions ultimately
modified the Roman administration itself, long before the Roman Empire ceased
to exist; and, even though the Greeks were compelled to adopt the civil law and
judicial forms of Rome, its political authority in the East was guided by the
feelings of the Greeks, and moulded according to Greek customs.
The social rank which the Greeks held in the eyes of their conquerors, at
the time of their subjection, is not to be overlooked. The bulk of the Greek
population in Europe consisted of landed proprietors, occupying a position
which would have given some rank in Roman society. No class precisely similar
existed at Rome, where a citizen that did not belong to the senate, the
aristocracy, or the administration, was of very little account, for the people
always remained in an inferior social rank. The higher classes at Rome always
felt either contempt or hostility towards the populace of the city; and even
when the emperors were induced to favour the people, from a wish to depress the
great families of the aristocracy, they were unable to efface the general
feeling of contempt with which the people was regarded. To the Greeks, — who
had always maintained a higher social position, not only in Europe, but also in
the kingdoms of the Seleucidae and the Ptolemies, — a high position was
conceded by the Roman aristocracy, as it awakened no feelings either of
hostility or jealousy. Polybius was an example.
Sect. II
Treatment of Greece after its Conquest
The Romans generally commenced by treating their provinces with mildness.
The government of Sicily was arranged on a basis which certainly did not
augment the burdens of the inhabitants. The tribute imposed on Macedonia was
less than the amount of taxation which had been previously paid to the native kings;
and there is no reason for supposing that the burdens of the Greeks, whose
country was embraced in the province of Achaia, were increased by the conquest.
The local municipal administration of the separate cities was allowed to exist,
but, in order to enforce submission more readily, their constitutions were
modified by fixing a census, which restricted the franchise in the democratic
commonwealths. Some states were long allowed to retain their own political
government, and were ranked as allies of the republic. It is impossible to
trace the changes which the Romans gradually effected in the financial and
administrative condition of Greece with chronological precision. Facts, often
separated by a long series of years, require to be gleaned; and caution must be
used in attributing to them a precise influence on the state of society at
other periods. The Roman senate was evidently not without great jealousy and
some fear of the Greeks; and great prudence was displayed in adopting a number
of measures by which they were gradually weakened, and cautiously broken to the
yoke of their conquerors. This caution proves that the despair of the Achaeans
had produced a considerable effect on the Romans, who perceived that the Greek
nation, if roused to a general combination, possessed the means of offering a
determined and dangerous resistance. Crete was not reduced into the form of a
Roman province until about eight years after the subjection of Achaia, and its
conquest was not effected without difficulty by a consular army during a war
which lasted three years. The resistance offered by the Cretans was so
determined that the island was almost depopulated before it could be conquered.
It was not until after the time of Augustus, when the conquest of every portion
of the Greek nation had been completed, that the Romans began to view the
Greeks in the contemptible light in which they are represented by later
writers.
No attempt was made to introduce uniformity into the general government of
the Grecian states; any such plan, indeed, would have been contrary to the
principles of the Roman government, which had never aspired at establishing
unity even in the administration of Italy. The attention of the Romans was
directed to the means of ruling their various conquests in the most efficient
manner, of concentrating all the military power in their own hands, and of
levying the greatest amount of tribute which circumstances would permit. Thus,
numerous cities in Greece, possessing but a very small territory, as Delphi,
Thespiae, Tanagra, and Elatea, were allowed to retain that degree of
independence, which secured to them the privilege of being governed by their
own laws and usages, so late even as the times of the emperors. Rhodes also
long preserved its own government as a free state, though it was completely
dependent on Rome. The Romans adopted no theoretical principles which required
them to enforce uniformity in the geographical divisions, or in the
administrative arrangements of the provinces of their empire, particularly
where local habits or laws opposed a barrier to any practical union.
The Roman government, however, early adopted measures tending to diminish
the resources of the Greek allies, and the condition of the servile population
which formed the bulk of the labouring classes was everywhere rendered very
hard to be endured. Two insurrections of slaves occurred in Sicily, and
contemporary with one of these there was a great rebellion of the slaves
employed in the silver mines of Attica, and tumults among the slaves at Delos
and in other parts of Greece. The Attic slaves seized the fortified town of
Sunium, and committed extensive ravages before the government of Athens was
able to overpower them. It is so natural for slaves to rebel when a favourable
occasion presents itself, that it is hazardous to look beyond ordinary causes
for any explanation of this insurrection, particularly as the declining state
of the silver mines of Laurium, at this period, rendered the slaves less
valuable, and would cause them to be worse treated, and more negligently
guarded. Still the simultaneous rebellion of slaves, in these distant
countries, seems not unconnected with the measures of the Roman government
towards its subjects. For we learn from Diodorus that the fiscal oppression of the
collectors of the tribute in Sicily was so great that free citizens were
reduced to slavery and sold in the slave markets as far as Bithynia.
If we could place implicit faith in the testimony of so firm and partial an
adherent of the Romans as Polybius, we must believe, that the Roman
administration was at first characterized by a love of justice, and that the
Roman magistrates were far less venal than the Greeks. If the Greeks, he says,
are intrusted with a single talent of public money, though they give written
security, and though legal witnesses be present, they will never act honestly;
but if the largest sums be confided to the Romans engaged in the public
service, their honourable conduct is secured simply by an oath. Under such
circumstances, the people must have appreciated highly the advantages of the
Roman domination, and contrasted the last years of their troubled and doubtful
independence with the just and peaceful government of Rome, in a manner
extremely favourable to their new masters. Less than a century of irresponsible
power effected a wonderful change in the conduct of the Roman magistrates.
Cicero declares, that the senate made a traffic of justice to the provincials.
There is nothing so holy, that it cannot be violated, nothing so strong, that
it cannot be destroyed by money, are his words. But as the government of Rome
grew more oppressive, and the amount of the taxes levied on the provinces was
more severely exacted, the increased power of the republic rendered any
rebellion of the Greeks utterly hopeless. The complete separation in the
administration of the various provinces, which were governed like so many
separate kingdoms, viceroyalties, or pashalics, and the preservation of a
distinct local government in each of the allied kingdoms and free states,
rendered their management capable of modification, without any compromise of
the general system of the republic; and this admirable fitness of its
administration to the exigencies of the times, remained an attribute of the
Roman state for many centuries. Each state in Greece, continuing in possession
of as much of its peculiar political constitution as was compatible with the
supremacy and fiscal views of a foreign conqueror, retained all its former
jealousies towards its neighbours, and its interests were likely to be as often
compromised by disputes with the surrounding Greek states as with the Roman
government. Prudence and local interests would everywhere favour submission to
Rome; national vanity alone would whisper incitements to venture on a struggle
for independence.
Sect. III
Effects of the Mithridattc War on the State of Greece
For sixty years after the conquest of Achaia, the Greeks remained docile
subjects of Rome. During that period, the policy of the government aided the
tendencies of society towards the accumulation of property in the hands of few
individuals. The number of Roman usurers increased, and the exactions of Roman
publicans became more oppressive, but the rich were the principal sufferers; so
that when the army of Mithridates invaded Greece, B. C. 86, while Rome appeared
plunged in anarchy by the civil broils of the partisans of Marius and Sulla,
the Greek aristocracy conceived the vain hope of recovering their independence.
When they saw the king drive the Romans out of Asia and transport a large army
into Europe, they expected him to rival the exploits of Hannibal, and to carry
the war into Italy. But the people in general did not take much interest in the
contest; they viewed it as a struggle for supremacy between the Romans and the
King of Pontus; and public opinion favoured the former, as likely to prove the
milder and more equitable masters. Many of the leading men in Greece, and the
governments of most of those states and cities which retained their
independence, declared in favour of Mithridates. Some Lacedaemonian and Achaian
troops joined his army, and Athens engaged heartily in his party. As soon,
however, as Sulla appeared in Greece with his army, every state hastened to
submit to Rome, with the exception of the Athenians, who probably had some
particular cause of dissatisfaction at this time. The vanity of the Athenians,
puffed up by constant allusions to their ancient power, induced them to engage
in a direct contest with the whole force of Rome. They were commanded by a
demagogue and philosopher named Aristion, whom they had elected Strategos and
intrusted with absolute power. The Roman legions were led by Sulla. The
exclusive vanity of the Athenians, while it cherished in their hearts a more
ardent love of liberty than had survived in the rest of Greece, blinded them to
their own insignificancy when compared with the belligerents into whose quarrel
they rashly thrust themselves. But though they rushed precipitately into the
war, they conducted themselves in it with great constancy. Sulla was compelled
to besiege Athens in person; and the defence of the city was conducted with
such courage and obstinacy, that the task of subduing it proved one of great
difficulty to a Roman army commanded by that celebrated warrior. When the
defence grew hopeless, the Athenians sent a deputation to Sulla to open
negotiations; but the orator beginning to recount the glories of their
ancestors at Marathon, as an argument for mercy, the proud Roman cut short the
discussion with the remark, that his country had sent him to Athens to punish
rebels, not to study history. Athens was at last taken by assault, and it was
treated by Sulla with unnecessary cruelty; the rapine of the troops was
encouraged, instead of being checked, by their general. The majority of the
citizens were slain; the carnage was so fearfully great, as to become memorable
even in that age of bloodshed; the private movable property was seized by the
soldiery, and Sulla assumed some merit to himself for not committing the rifled
houses to the flames. He declared that he saved the city from destruction, and
allowed Athens to continue to exist, only on account of its ancient glory. He
carried off some of the columns of the temple of Jupiter Olympius, to ornament
Rome; but as that temple was in an unfinished state, and he inflicted no injury
on any public building, it seems probable that he only removed materials which
were ready for transport, without pulling down any part of the edifice. From
the treasury of the Parthenon, however, he carried off 40 talents of gold and
600 of silver. The fate of the Piraeus, which he utterly destroyed, was more
severe than that of Athens. From Sulla’s campaign in Greece, the commencement
of the ruin and depopulation of the country is to be dated. The destruction of
property caused by his ravages in Attica was so great, that Athens from that
time lost its commercial as well as its political importance. The race of
Athenian citizens was almost extirpated, and a new population, composed of a
heterogeneous mass of settlers, received the right of citizenships. Still as
Sulla left Athens in possession of freedom and autonomia, with the rank of an
allied city, the vitality of Greek institutions inspired the altered body; the
ancient forms and laws continued to exist in their former purity, and the
Areopagus is mentioned by Tacitus, in the reign of Tiberius, as nobly
disregarding the powerful protection of Piso, who strove to influence its
decisions and corrupt the administration of justice.
Athens was not the only city in Greece which suffered severely from the
cruelty and rapacity of Sulla. He plundered Delos, Delphi, Olympia, and the
sacred enclosure of Aesculapius, near Epidaurus; and he razed Anthedon,
Larymna, and Halae to the ground. After he had defeated Archelaus, the general
of Mithridates, at Chaeronea, he deprived Thebes of half its territory, which
he consecrated to Apollo and Jupiter. The administration of the temporal
affairs of the pagan deities was not so wisely conducted as the civil business
of the municipalities. The Theban territory declined in wealth and population
under the care of the two gods, and in the time of Pausanias the Cadmea or
citadel was the only inhabited portion of ancient Thebes. Both parties, during
the Mithridatic war, inflicted severe injuries on Greece, plundered the
country, and destroyed property most wantonly. Many of the losses were never
repaired. The foundations of national prosperity were undermined; and it
henceforward became impossible to save from the annual consumption of the
inhabitants the sums necessary to replace the accumulated capital of ages,
which this short war had annihilated. In some cases the wealth of the
communities became insufficient to keep the existing public works in repair.
Sect. IV
Ruin of the Country by the Pirates of Cilicia
The Greeks, far from continuing to enjoy permanent tranquillity under the
powerful protection of Rome, found themselves exposed to the attacks of every
enemy, against whom the policy of their masters did not require the employment
of a regular army. The conquest of the eastern shores of the Mediterranean by
the Romans destroyed the maritime police which had been enforced by the Greek
states as long as they possessed an independent navy. Even Rhodes, after its
services ceased to be indispensable, was watched with jealousy, though it had
remained firmly attached to Rome and given asylum to numbers of Roman citizens
who fled from Asia Minor to escape death at the hands of the partisans of
Mithridates. The caution of the senate did not allow the provinces to maintain
any considerable armed force, either by land or sea; and the guards whom the
free cities were permitted to keep, were barely sufficient to protect the walls
of their citadels. Armies of robbers and fleets of pirates, remains of the
mercenary forces of the Asiatic monarchs, disbanded in consequence of the Roman
victories, began to infest the coasts of Greece. As long as the provinces
continued able to pay their taxes with regularity, and the trade of Rome did
not suffer directly, little attention was paid to the sufferings of the Greeks.
The geographical configuration of European Greece, intersected, in every
direction, by high and rugged mountains, and separated by deep gulfs and bays
into a number of promontories and peninsulas, renders communication between the
thickly peopled and fertile districts more difficult than in most other
regions. The country opposes barriers to internal trade, and presents
difficulties to the formation of plans of mutual defence between the different
districts, which it requires care and judgment, on the part of the general
government, to remove. The armed force that can instantly be collected at one
point, must often be small; and this circumstance has marked out Greece as a
suitable field where piratical bands may plunder, as they have it in their
power to remove their forces to distant spots with great celerity. From the
earliest ages of history to the present day, these circumstances, combined with
the extensive trade which has always been carried on in the eastern part of the
Mediterranean, have rendered the Grecian seas the scene of constant piracies.
At many periods, the pirates have been able to assemble forces sufficient to
give their expeditions the character of regular war ; and their pursuits have
been so lucrative, and their success so great, that their profession has ceased
to be viewed as a dishonourable occupation.
A system of piracy, which was carried on by considerable armies and large
fleets, began to be formed soon after the conclusion of the Mithridatic war.
The indefinite nature of the Roman power in the East, the weakness of the
Asiatic monarchs and of the sovereigns of Egypt, the questionable nature of the
protection which Rome accorded to her allies, and the general disarming of the
European Greeks, all encouraged and facilitated the enterprises of these
pirates. A political, as well as a military organization, was given to their
forces by the seizure of several strong positions on the coast of Cilicia. From
these stations they directed their expeditions over the greater part of the
Mediterranean. The wealth which ages of prosperity had accumulated in the many
towns and temples of Greece was now defenceless; the country was exposed to
daily incursions, and a long list of the devastations of the Cilician pirates
is recorded in history. Many even of the largest and wealthiest cities in
Europe and Asia were successfully attacked and plundered, and the greater
number of the celebrated temples of antiquity were robbed of their immense
treasures. Samos, Clazomene, and Samothrace, the great temples at Hermione,
Epidaurus, Taenarus, Calauria, Actium, Argos, and the Isthmus of Corinth, were
all pillaged. To such an extent was this system of robbery carried, and so
powerful and well-disciplined were the forces of the pirates, that it was at
last necessary for Rome either to share with them the dominion of the sea, or
to devote all her military energies to their destruction. In order to destroy
these last remains of the mercenaries who had upheld the Macedonian empire in
the East, Pompey was invested with extraordinary powers as commander-in-chief
over the whole Mediterranean. An immense force was placed at his absolute
disposal, and he was charged with a degree of authority over the officers of
the republic, and the allies of the State, which had never before been
intrusted to one individual. His success in the execution of this commission
was considered one of his most brilliant military achievements; he captured
ninety ships with brazen beaks, and took twenty thousand prisoners. Some of
these prisoners were established in towns on the coast of Cilicia; and Soli, which
he rebuilt, and peopled with these pirates, was honoured with the name of
Pompeiopolis. The Romans, consequently, do not seem to have regarded them as
having engaged in a disgraceful warfare, otherwise Pompey would hardly have
ventured to make them his clients.
The proceedings of the senate during the piratical war revealed to the
Greeks the full extent of the disorganization which already prevailed in the
Roman government. A few families who considered themselves above the law, and
who submitted to no moral restraint, ruled both the senate and the people, so
that the policy of the republic changed and vacillated according to the
interests and passions of a small number of leading men in Rome. Some events
during the conquest of Crete afford a remarkable instance of the incredible
disorder in the republic, which foreshadowed the necessity of a single despot
as the only escape from anarchy. While Pompey, with unlimited power over the
shores and islands of the Mediterranean, was exterminating piracy and converting
pirates into citizens, Metellus, under the authority of the senate, was engaged
in conquering the island of Crete, in order to add it to the list of Roman
provinces of which the senate alone named the governors. A conflict of
authority arose between Pompey and Metellus. The latter was cruel and firm; the
former mild but ambitious, and eager to render the whole maritime population of
the East his dependents. He became jealous of the success of Metellus, and sent
one of his lieutenants to stop the siege of the Cretan towns invested by the
Roman army. But Metellus was not deterred by seeing the ensigns of Pompey’s
authority displayed from the walls. He pursued his conquests, and neither
Pompey nor the times were yet prepared for an open civil war between consular
armies.
Crete had been filled with the strongholds of the pirates as well as
Cilicia, and there is no doubt that their ranks were filled with Greeks who
could find no other means of subsistence. Despair is said to have driven many
of the citizens of the states conquered by the Romans to suicide; it must have
forced a far greater number to embrace a life of piracy and robbery. The
government of Rome was at this time subject to continual revolutions; and the
Romans lost all respect for the rights of property either at home or abroad.
Wealth and power were the only objects of pursuit, and the force of all moral
ties was broken. Justice ceased to be administered, and men, in such cases,
always assume the right of revenging their own wrongs. Those who considered
themselves aggrieved by any act of oppression, or fancied they had received
some severe injury, sought revenge in the way which presented itself most
readily; and when the oppressor was secure against their attacks, they made
society responsible. The state of public affairs was considered an apology for
the ravages of the pirates even in those districts of Greece which suffered
most severely from their lawless conduct. They probably spent liberally among
the poor the treasures which they wrested from the rich; and so little, indeed,
were they placed beyond the pale of society, that Pompey himself settled a
colony of them at Dyme, in Achaia, where they seem to have prospered. Though
piracy was not subsequently carried on so extensively as to merit a place in
history, it was not entirely extirpated even by the fleet which the Roman
emperors maintained in the East; and that cases still continued to occur in the
Grecian seas is proved by public inscriptions. The carelessness of the senate
in superintending the administration of the distant provinces caused a great
increase of social corruption, and left crimes against the property and persons
of the provincials often unpunished. Kidnapping by land and sea became a
regular profession. The great slave-mart of Delos enabled the man-stealers to
sell thousands in a single day. Even open brigandage was allowed to exist in
the heart of the eastern provinces at the time of Rome’s greatest power. Strabo
mentions several robber chiefs who maintained themselves in their fastnesses
like independent princes.
Sect. V
Nature of the Roman Provincial Administration in Greece
The Romans reduced those countries where they met with resistance into the
form of provinces, a procedure which was generally equivalent to abrogating the
existing laws, and imposing on the vanquished a new system of civil as well as
political administration. In the countries inhabited by the Greeks this policy
underwent considerable modification. The Greeks, indeed, were so much farther
advanced in civilization than the Romans, that it was no easy task for a Roman
proconsul to effect any great change in the civil administration. He could not
organize his government, without borrowing largely from the existing laws of
the province. The constitution of Sicily, which was the first Greek province of
the Roman dominions, presents a number of anomalies in the administration of
its different districts. That portion of the island which had composed the
kingdom of Hiero was allowed to retain its own laws, and paid the Romans the
same amount of taxation which had been formerly levied by its own monarchs. The
other portions of the island were subjected to various regulations concerning
the amount of their taxes and the administration of justice. The province
contained three allied cities, five colonies, five free and seventeen tributary
cities. Macedonia, Epirus, and Achaia, when conquered, were treated very much
in the same way, if we make due allowance for the increasing severity of the
fiscal government of the Roman magistrates. Macedonia, before it was reduced to
the condition of a province, was divided into four districts, each of which was
governed by its own magistrates elected by the people. When Achaia was
conquered, the walls of the towns were thrown down, the aristocracy was ruined,
and the country impoverished by fines. But as soon as the Romans were convinced
that Greece was too weak to be dangerous, the Achaeans were allowed to revive
some of their old civic usages and federal institutions. As the province of
Achaia embraced the Peloponnesus, northern Greece, and southern Epirus, the
revival of local confederacies, and the privileges accorded to free cities and
particular districts, really tended to disunite the Greeks, without affording
them the means of increasing their national strength. Crete, Cyprus, Cyrene,
and Asia Minor were subsequently reduced to provinces, and were allowed to
retain much of their laws and usages. Thrace, even so late as the time of
Tiberius, was governed by its own sovereign, as an ally of the Romans. Many
cities within the bounds of the provinces retained their own peculiar laws,
and, as far as their own citizens were concerned, they continued to possess the
legislative as well as the executive power, by administering their own affairs,
and executing justice within their limits, without being liable to the control
of the proconsul.
As long as the republic continued to exist, the provinces were administered
by proconsuls or praetors, chosen from among the members of the senate, and
responsible to that body for their administration. The authority of these
provincial governors was immense; they had the power of life and death over the
Greeks, and the supreme control over all judicial, financial, and
administrative business was vested in their hands. They had the right of naming
and removing most of the judges and magistrates under their orders, and most of
the fiscal arrangements regarding the provincials depended on their will. No
power ever existed more liable to be abused; for while the representatives of
the most absolute sovereigns have seldom been intrusted with more extensive
authority, they have never incurred so little danger of being punished for its
abuse. The only tribunal before which the proconsuls could be cited for any
acts of injustice which they might commit was that very senate which had sent
them out as its deputies, and received them back into its body as members.
When the imperial government was consolidated by Augustus, the command of
the whole military force of the republic devolved on the emperor; but his
constitutional position was not that of sovereign. The early emperors
concentrated in their persons the offices of commander-in-chief of the military
and naval forces of Rome, of minister of war and of finance, and of Pontifex
Maximus, which gave them a sacred character, as head of the religion of the
State, and their persons were inviolable, as they were invested with the
tribunician power; but the senate and people were still possessed of the
supreme legislative authority, and the senate continued to direct the civil
branches of the executive ad-ministration. In consequence of this relation
between the jurisdiction of the senate and the emperors, the provinces were
divided into two classes: Those in which the military forces were stationed
were placed under the direct orders of the emperor, and were governed by his
lieutenants or legates; the other provinces, which did not require to be
constantly occupied by the legions, remained dependent on the senate, as the
chief civil authority in the State, and were governed by proconsuls or
propraetors. Most of the countries inhabited by the Greeks were in that
peaceable condition which placed them in the rank of senatorial provinces.
Sicily, Macedonia, Epirus, Achaia, Crete, Cyrene, Bithynia, and Asia Minor
remained under the control of the senate. Cyprus, from its situation as
affording a convenient post for a military force to watch Cilicia, Syria, and
Egypt, was at first classed among the imperial provinces; but Augustus
subsequently exchanged it for the more important position of Dalmatia, where an
army could be stationed to watch Rome, and separate Italy and the proconsular provinces
of Greece.
The proconsuls and propraetors occupied a higher rank in the State than the
imperial legates; but their situation deprived them of all hope of military
distinction, the highest object of Roman ambition. This exclusion of the
aristocracy from military pursuits, by the emperors, is not to be lost sight of
in observing the change which took place in the Roman character. Avarice was
the vice which succeeded in stifling feelings of self-abasement and
disappointed ambition; and as the proconsuls were not objects of jealousy to
the emperors, they were enabled to gratify their ruling passion without danger.
They surrounded themselves with a splendid court; and a numerous train of
followers, officials, and guards, who were at their orders, was maintained at
the expense of their province. As they were themselves senators, they felt
assured of finding favourable judges in the senate under any circumstances.
Irresponsible government soon degenerates into tyranny, and the administration
of the Roman proconsuls became as oppressive as that of the worst despots, and
was loudly complained of by the provincials. The provinces under the government
of the emperor were better administered. The imperial lieutenants, though
inferior in rank to proconsuls, possessed a more extensive command, as they
united in their persons the chief civil and military authority. The effect of
their possessing more power was, that the limits of their authority, and the
forms of their proceedings, were determined with greater precision — were more
closely watched, and more strictly controlled by the military discipline to
which they were subjected; while, at the same time, the constant dependence of
all their actions on the immediate orders of the emperor and the various
departments of which he was the head opposed more obstacles to arbitrary
proceedings.
The expenses of the proconsular administration being paid by the provinces,
it was chiefly by abuses augmenting their amount that the proconsuls were
enabled to accumulate enormous fortunes during their short tenure of
government. The burden was so heavily felt by Macedonia and Achaia, even as
early as the reign of Tiberius, that the complaints of these two provinces
induced that emperor to unite their administration with that of the imperial
province of Moesia; but Claudius restored them to the senate. Thrace, when it
was reduced to a Roman province by Vespasian, was also added to the imperial
list. As the power of the emperors rose into absolute authority over the Roman
world and the pageant of the republic faded away, all distinction between the
different classes of provinces disappeared. They were distributed according to
the wish of the reigning emperor, and their administration arbitrarily
transferred to officers of whatever rank he thought fit to select. The Romans,
indeed, had never affected much system in this, any more than in any other
branch of their government. Pontius Pilate, when he condemned our Saviour,
governed Judaea with the rank of procurator of Caesar; he was vested with the
whole administrative, judicial, fiscal, and military authority, almost as
completely as it could have been exercised by a proconsul, yet his title was
only that of a finance officer, charged with the administration of those
revenues which belonged to the imperial treasury.
The provincial governors usually named three or four deputies to carry on
the business of the districts into which the province was divided, and each of
these deputies was controlled and assisted by a local council. It may be
remarked, that the condition of the inhabitants of the western portion of the
Roman Empire was different from that of the eastern; in the west the people
were generally treated as little better than serfs; they were not considered
the absolute proprietors of the lands they cultivated. Hadrian first gave them
a full right of property in their lands, and secured to them a regular system
of law. In Greece, on the other hand, the people retained all their property
and private rights. Some rare exceptions indeed occurred, as in the case of the
Corinthian territory, which was confiscated for the benefit of the Roman state,
and declared ager publicus after the
destruction of the city by Mummius. Throughout all the countries inhabited by
the Greeks, the provincial administration was necessarily modified by the
circumstance of the conquered being much farther advanced in social
civilization than their conquerors. To facilitate the task of governing and
taxing the Greeks, the Romans found themselves compelled to retain much of the
civil government, and many of the financial arrangements, which they found
existing; and hence arose the marked difference which is observed in the
administration of the eastern and western portions of the empire. When the
great jurist Scaevola was proconsul of Asia, he published an edict for the
administration of his province, by which he allowed the Greeks to have judges
of their own nation, and to decide their suits according to their own laws; a
concession equivalent to the restoration of their civil liberties in public
opinion, according to Cicero, who copied it when he was proconsul of Cilicia.
The existence of the free cities, of the local tribunals and provincial
assemblies, and the respect paid to their laws, gave the Greek language an
official character, and enabled the Greeks to acquire so great an influence in
the administration of their country, as either to limit the despotic power of
their Roman masters, or, when that proved impossible, to share its profits. But
though the arbitrary decisions of the proconsuls received some check from the
existence of fixed rules and permanent usages, still these barriers were
insufficient to prevent the abuse of irresponsible authority. Those laws and
customs which a proconsul dared not openly violate, he could generally nullify
by some concealed measure of oppression. The avidity displayed by Brutus in
endeavouring to make Cicero enforce payment of forty-eight per cent, interest
when his debtors, the Salaminians of Cyprus, offered to pay the capital with
twelve per cent, interest, proves with what injustice and oppression the Greeks
were treated even by the mildest of the Roman aristocracy. The fact that
throughout the Grecian provinces, as well as in the rest of the empire, the
governors superintended the financial administration, and exercised the
judicial power, is sufficient to explain the ruin and poverty which the Roman
government produced. Before the wealth of the people had been utterly consumed,
an equitable proconsul had it in his power to confer happiness on his
provinces, and Cicero draws a very favourable picture of his own administration
in Cilicia: but a few governors like Verres and Caius Antonius soon reduced a
province to a state of poverty, from which it would have required ages of good
government to enable it to recover. The private letters of Cicero afford
repeated proofs that the majority of the officers employed by the Roman
government openly violated every principle of justice to gratify their passions
and their avarice. Many of them even condescended to engage in trade, and, like
Brutus, became usurers.
The early years of the empire were certainly more popular than the latter
years of the republic in the provinces. The emperors were anxious to strengthen
themselves against the senate by securing the goodwill of the provincials, and
they consequently exerted their authority to check the oppressive conduct of
the senatorial officers, and to lighten the fiscal burdens of the people by a
stricter administration of justice. Tiberius, Claudius, and Domitian, though
Rome groaned under their tyranny, were remarkable for their zeal in correcting
abuses in the administration of justice, and Hadrian established a council of
jurisconsults and senators to assist him in reviewing the judicial business of
the provinces as well as of the capital.
Sect. VI
Fiscal Administration of the Romans
The legal amount of the taxes, direct and indirect, levied by the Romans on
the Greeks, was probably not greater than the sum paid to their national
governments in the days of their independence. But a small amount of taxation
arbitrarily imposed, unjustly collected, and injudiciously spent, weighs more heavily
on the resources of the people, than immense burdens properly distributed and
wisely employed. The wealth and resources of Greece had been greatest at the
time when each city formed a separate state, and the inhabitants of each valley
possessed the power of employing the taxes which they paid, for objects which
ameliorated their own condition. The moment the centralization of political
power enabled one city to appropriate the revenues of another to its wants,
whether for its architectural embellishment or for its public games, theatrical
representations, and religious ceremonies, the decline of the country
commenced: but all the evil effects of centralization were not felt until the
taxes were paid to foreigners. When the tributes were remitted to Rome, it was
difficult to persuade absent administrators of the necessity of expending money
on a road, a port, or an aqueduct, which had no direct connection with Roman
interests. Had the Roman government acted according to the strictest principles
of justice, Greece must have suffered from its dominion; but its avarice and
corruption, after the commencement of the civil wars, knew no bounds. The
extraordinary payments levied on the provinces soon equalled, and sometimes
exceeded, the regular and legal taxes. Sparta and Athens, as allied states,
were exempt from direct taxation; but, in order to preserve their liberty, they
were compelled to make voluntary offerings to the Roman generals, who held the
fate of the East in their hands, and these sometimes equalled the amount of any
ordinary tribute. Cicero supplies ample proof of the extortions committed by
the proconsuls, and no arrangements were adopted to restrain their avarice
until the time of Augustus. It is, therefore, only under the empire that any
accurate picture of the fiscal administration of the Romans in Greece can be
attempted.
Until the time of Augustus, the Romans had maintained their armies by
seizing and squandering the accumulated capital hoarded by all the nations of
the world. They emptied the treasuries of all the kings and states they
conquered; and when Julius Caesar marched to Rome, he dissipated that portion
of the plunder of the world which had been laid up in the coffers of the
republic. When that source of riches was exhausted, Augustus found himself
compelled to seek for regular funds for maintaining the army: “And it came to
pass in those days, that there went out a decree from Caesar Augustus that all
the world should be taxed”. A regular survey of the whole empire was made, and
the land-tax was assessed according to a valuation taken of the annual income
of every species of property. A capitation-tax was also imposed on all the
provincials whom the land-tax did not affect.
The ordinary provincial taxes in the East were this land-tax, which
generally amounted to a tenth of the produce, though, in some cases, it
constituted a fifth, and in others fell to a twentieth. The land-tax was
rendered uniform in all the provinces and converted at last into a money
payment, by Marcus Aurelius. It was not assessed annually: but a valuation was
made at stated periods for a determinate number of years, and the annual amount
was called the Indictio before the
time of Constantine, when the importance of this fiscal measure to the
well-being of the inhabitants of the Roman empire is attested by the cycle of
indictions becoming the ordinary chronological record of time. Italy itself was
subjected to the land-tax and capitation by Galerius, A.D. 306, but the first
indiction of the cycle of fifteen years used for chronological notation
commenced on the 1st of September 312. The subjects of the empire paid also a
tax on cattle, and a variety of duties on importation and exportation, which
were levied even on the conveyance of goods from one province to another. In
Greece, the free cities also retained the right of levying local duties on
their citizens. Contributions of provisions and manufactures were likewise
exacted for feeding and clothing the troops stationed in the provinces. Even
under Augustus, who devoted his personal attention to reforming the financial
administration of the empire, the proconsuls and provincial governors continued
to avail themselves of their position, as a means of gratifying their avarice.
Licinus accumulated immense riches in Gaul. Tiberius perceived that the weight
of the Roman fiscal system was pressing too severely on the provinces, and he
rebuked the prefect of Egypt for remitting too large a sum to Rome, as the
amount proved he had overtaxed his province. The mere fact of a prefect’s
possessing the power of increasing or diminishing the amount of his remittances
to the treasury, is enough to condemn the arbitrary nature of the Roman fiscal
administration. The prefect was told by the emperor that a good shepherd should
shear, not flay, his sheep. But no rulers ever estimated correctly the amount
of taxes that their subjects could advantageously pay; and Tiberius received a
lesson on the financial system of his empire from Baton, King of Dalmatia, who,
on being asked the cause of a rebellion, replied, that it arose from the
emperor’s sending wolves to guard his flocks instead of shepherds.
The financial policy of the Roman republic was to transfer as much of the
money circulating in the provinces, and of the precious metals in the hands of
private individuals, as it was possible, into the coffers of the State. The
city of Rome formed a drain for the wealth of all the provinces, and the whole
empire was impoverished for its support. When Caligula expressed the wish that
the Roman people had only one neck, in order that he might destroy them all at
a single blow, the idea found a responsive echo in many a breast. There was a
wise moral in the sentiment uttered in his frenzy; and many felt that the
dispersion of the immense pauper population of Rome, which was nourished in
idleness by the public revenues, would have been a great benefit to the rest of
the empire. The desire of seizing wealth wherever it could be found continued
to be long the dominant feeling in the personal policy of the emperors, as well
as the proconsuls. The provincial governors enriched themselves by plundering
their subjects, and the emperors filled their treasuries by accusing the
senators of those crimes which entailed confiscation of their fortunes. From
the earliest periods of Roman history, down to the time of Justinian,
confiscation of private property was considered an ordinary and important
branch of the imperial revenue. When Alexander the Great conquered Asia, the
treasures which he dispersed increased the commerce of the world, created new
cities, and augmented the general wealth of mankind. The Romans collected far
greater riches from their conquests than Alexander had done, as they pushed
their exactions much farther; but the rude state of society, in which they
lived at the time of their first great successes, prevented their perceiving,
that by carrying off or destroying all the movable capital in their conquests,
they must ultimately diminish the amount of their own revenues. The wealth
brought away from the countries inhabited by the Greeks was incredible; for the
Romans pillaged the conquered, as the Spaniards plundered Mexico and Peru, and
ruled them as the Turks subsequently governed Greece. The riches which
centuries of industry had accumulated in Syracuse, Tarentum, Epirus, Macedonia,
and Greece, and the immense sums seized in the treasuries of the kings of
Cyprus, Pergamus, Syria, and Egypt, were removed to Rome, and consumed in a way
which virtually converted them into premiums for neglecting agriculture. They
were dispersed in paying an immense army, in feeding an idle populace, which
was thus withdrawn from all productive occupations, and in maintaining the
household of the emperor, the senators, and the imperial freedmen. The
consequence of the arrangements adopted for provisioning Rome was felt over the
whole empire, and seriously affected the prosperity of the most distant
provinces. It is necessary to notice them, in order to understand perfectly the
financial system of the empire during three centuries.
The citizens of Rome were considered entitled to a share of the revenues of
the provinces which they had conquered, and which were long regarded in the
light of a landed estate of the republic. The Roman State was held to be under
an obligation of supporting all who were liable to military service, if they
were poor and without profitable employment. The history of the public
distributions of grain, and of the measures adopted for securing ample supplies
to the market, at low prices, forms an important chapter in the social and
political records of the Roman people. An immense quantity of grain was
distributed in this way, which was received as tribute from the provinces.
Caesar found three hundred and twenty thousand persons receiving this gratuity.
It is true he reduced the number one half. The grain was drawn from Sicily,
Africa, and Egypt, and its distribution enabled the poor to live in idleness,
while the arrangements adopted by the Roman government, for selling grain at a
low price, rendered the cultivation of land around Rome unprofitable to its
proprietors. A large sum was annually employed by the State in purchasing grain
in the provinces, and in transporting it to Rome, where it was sold to the
bakers at a fixed price. A premium was also paid to the private importers of
grain, in order to insure an abundant supply. In this manner a very large sum
was expended to keep bread cheap in a city where a variety of circumstances
tended to make it dear. This singular system of annihilating capital, and
ruining agriculture and industry, was so deeply rooted in the Roman
administration, that similar gratuitous distributions of grain were established
at Antioch and Alexandria, and other cities, and they were introduced at
Constantinople when that city became the capital of the empire.
It is not surprising that Greece suffered severely under a government
equally tyrannical in its conduct and unjust in its legislation. In almost
every department of public business the interests of the State were placed in
opposition to those of the people, and even when the letter of the law was
mild, its administration was burdensome. The customs of Rome were moderate, and
consisted of a duty of five per cent, on exports and imports. Where the customs
were so reasonable, commerce ought to have flourished; but the real amount
levied under an unjust government bears no relation to the nominal payment. The
government of Turkey has ruined the commerce of its subjects, with duties
equally moderate. The Romans despised commerce; they considered merchants as
little better than cheats, and concluded that they were always in the wrong
when they sought to avoid making any payment to government. The provinces in
the eastern part of the Mediterranean are inhabited by a mercantile population.
The wants of many parts can only be supplied by sea; and as the various
provinces and small independent states were often separated by double lines of
custom-houses, the subsistence of the population was frequently at the mercy of
the revenue officers. The customs payable to Rome were let to farmers, who
possessed extensive powers for their collection, and a special tribunal existed
for the enforcement of their claims; these farmers of the customs were
consequently powerful tyrants in all the countries round the Aegean Sea.
The ordinary duty on the transport of goods from one province to another
amounted to two and a half per cent.; but some kinds of merchandise were
subjected to a tax of an eighth, which appears to have been levied when the article
first entered the Roman Empire.
The provincial contributions pressed as heavily on the Greeks as the
general taxes. The expense of the household of the proconsuls was very great;
they had also the right of placing the troops in winter quarters, in whatever
towns they thought fit. This power was rendered a profitable means of extorting
money from the wealthy districts. Cicero mentions that the island of Cyprus
paid two hundred talents — about forty-five thousand pounds annually — in order
to purchase exemption from this burden. The power of the fiscal agents, charged
to collect the extraordinary contributions in the provinces, was unlimited. One
of the ordinary punishments for infringing the revenue laws was confiscation, —
a punishment which was converted by the collectors of the revenue into a
systematic means of extortion. A regular trade in usury was established, in
order to force proprietors to sell their property; and accusations were brought
forward in the fiscal courts, merely to levy fines, or compel the accused to
incur debts. Free Greeks were constantly sold as slaves because they were
unable to pay the amount of taxation to which they were liable. The
establishment of posts, which Augustus instituted for the transmission of
military orders, was soon converted into a burden on the provinces, instead of
being rendered a public benefit, by allowing private individuals to make use of
its services. The enlisting of recruits was another source of abuse. Privileges
and monopolies were granted to merchants and manufacturers; the industry of a
province was ruined, to raise a sum of money for an emperor or a favourite.
The free cities and allied states were treated with as much injustice as
the provinces, though their position enabled them to escape many of the public
burdens. The crowns of gold, which had once been given by cities and provinces
as a testimony of gratitude, were converted into a forced gift, and at last
extorted as a tax of a fixed amount.
In addition to the direct weight of the public burdens, their severity was
increased by the exemption which Roman citizens enjoyed from the land-tax, the
customs, and the municipal burdens, in the provinces, the free cities, and the
allied states. This exemption filled Greece with traders and usurers, who
obtained the right of citizenship as a speculation, merely to evade the payment
of the local taxes. The Roman magistrates had the power of granting this
immunity; and as they were in the habit of participating in the profits even of
their enfranchised slaves, there can be no doubt that a regular traffic in
citizenship was established, and this cause exercised considerable influence in
accelerating the ruin of the allied states and free cities, by defrauding them
of their local privileges and revenues. When Nero wished to render himself
popular in Greece, he extended the immunity from tribute to all the Greeks; but
Vespasian found the financial affairs of the empire in such disorder that he
was compelled to revoke all grants of exemption to the provinces. Virtue, in
the old times of Rome, meant valour; liberty, in the time of Nero, signified
freedom from taxation. Of this liberty Vespasian deprived Greece, Byzantium,
Samos, Rhodes, and Lycia.
The financial administration of the Romans inflicted, if possible, a
severer blow on the moral constitution of society than on the material
prosperity of the country. It divided the population of Greece into two
classes, one possessing the title of Roman citizens, — a title often purchased
by their wealth, and which implied freedom from taxation; — the other
consisting of the Greeks who, from poverty, were unable to purchase the envied
privilege, and thus by their very poverty were compelled to bear the whole
weight of the public burdens laid on the province. The rich and poor were thus
ranged in two separate castes of society.
By the Roman constitution, the knights were intrusted with the management
of the finances of the State. They were a body in whose eyes wealth, on which
their rank substantially depended, possessed an undue value. The prominent
feature of their character was avarice, notwithstanding the praises of their
justice which Cicero has left us. The knights acted as collectors of the
revenues, but they also frequently farmed the taxes of a province for a term of
years, subletting portions, and they formed companies for farming the customs
besides employing capital in public or private loans. They were favoured by the
policy of Rome; while their own riches, and their secondary position in
political affairs, served to screen them from attacks in the forum. For a long
period, too, all the judges were selected from their order, and consequently
knights alone decided those commercial questions which most seriously affected
their individual profits.
The heads of the financial administration in Greece were thus placed in a
moral position unfavourable to an equitable collection of the revenues. The
case of Brutus, who attempted to oblige the Salaminians of Cyprus to pay him
compound interest, at the rate of four per cent, a month, shows that avarice
and extortion were not generally considered dishonourable in the eyes of the
Roman aristocracy. The practices of selling the right of citizenship, of
raising unjust fiscal prosecutions to extort fines, and enforce confiscation to
increase landed estates, have been already mentioned. They produced effects
which have found a place in history. The existence of all these crimes is well
known; their effects may be observed in the fact that a single citizen, Julius
Eurycles, had in the time of Augustus rendered himself proprietor of the whole
island of Cythera, and caused a rebellion in Laconia by the severity of his
extortions. During the republic the authority of Romans of high rank was so
great in the provinces that no Greek ventured to dispute their commands. Caius
Antonius, the colleague of Cicero in the consulship, resided at Cephalonia when
he was banished for extortion, and Strabo informs us that this criminal treated
the inhabitants as if the island had been his private property.
Roman citizens in Greece escaped the oppressive powers of the fiscal
agents, not only in those cases wherein they were by law exempt from provincial
taxes, but also because they possessed the means of defending themselves
against injustice by the right of carrying their causes to Rome for judgment by
appeal. These privileges rendered the number of Roman citizens engaged in
mercantile speculation and trade very great. A considerable multitude of the
inhabitants of Rome had, from the earliest times, been employed in trade and
commerce, without obtaining the right of citizenship at home. They did not fail
to settle in numbers in all the Roman conquests, and, in the provinces, they
were correctly called Romans. They always enjoyed from the republic the fullest
protection, and soon acquired the rights of citizenship. Even Roman citizens
were sometimes so numerous in the provinces that they could furnish not a few
recruits to the legions. Their numbers were so great at the commencement of the
Mithridatic war (B. C. 88) that eighty thousand were put to death in Asia when
the king took up arms against the Romans. The greater part undoubtedly
consisted of merchants, traders, and money-dealers. The Greeks at last obtained
the right of Roman citizenship in such multitudes, that Nero may have made no
very enormous sacrifice of public revenue when he conferred liberty, or freedom
from tribute, on all the Greeks.
It is unnecessary to dwell at any length on the effects of the system of
general oppression and partial privileges which has been described. Honest
industry was useless in trade, and political intrigue was the easiest mode of
obtaining some privilege or monopoly which ensured the speedy accumulation of a
large fortuned
In enumerating the causes of the impoverishment and depopulation of the
Roman Empire, the depreciation of the coinage must not be overlooked.
Considerable changes were made in the Roman mint by Augustus, but the great
depreciation which destroyed capital, diminished the demand for labour, and
accelerated the depopulation of the provinces, dates from the reign of
Caracalla.
Augustus fixed the standard at 40 gold pieces (aurei) to a pound of pure gold and he coined 84 denarii from a
pound of silver, but he did not always observe strictly the standard which he
had established. And in the interval between his reign and that of Nero coins
of less than the legal standard were frequently minted. Nero reduced the
standard to 45 aurei to a pound of
gold and coined 96 denarii from a
pound of silver, retaining the proportion of 25 denarii to an aureus.
Caracalla again reduced the standard, coining 50 aurei from a pound of gold and making a great addition of alloy in
the silver coinage. Great irregularities were not uncommon in the Roman mint at
every period under the republic and the empire. Indeed, order and system appear
to have been introduced very slowly into some branches of the Roman
administration, and great irregularities were of constant recurrence in the
mint. Temporary necessities caused the legal standard to be at times lowered
and at others violated even in the best days of the republic, and the arbitrary
power of the emperors is more completely exhibited in the coinage than in the
historical records of the empire. Before the time of Nero aurei were coined of 45 to a pound, and before the time of
Caracalla of 50 to a pound.
In the time of Diocletian a great change was made in the coinage when every
other branch of the administration was reformed. The standard was fixed at 60 aurei to a pound of pure gold, but this
rate was not preserved for any length of time, and in the reign of Constantine
the Great 72 gold pieces were coined from a pound of metal. Order and unity
were at last introduced into the fabric of the Roman government, but, as too
often happens in the history of human institutions, we find these benefits
obtained by the loss of local rights and personal liberty. The gold standard
adopted by Constantine became one of the immutable institutions of the Roman
Empire, and it was retained until the eastern empire was extinguished by the
conquest of Constantinople in 1204. These pieces, called at first solidi, and known afterwards to the
western nations by the name of byzants, were minted without change in the
weight and purity of the metal for a period of nearly 900 years.
The public taxes and the tribute of the provinces were generally exacted in
gold. It was therefore the interest of the emperors to maintain the purity of
the gold coinage. But as large payments were made by weight, a profit could
often be made by issuing from the mint coins of less than the standard weight,
and that this fraud was often perpetrated by the emperors is attested by the
existence of innumerable well- preserved gold coins.
The silver coinage was in a different condition from the gold. From the
time of Augustus to that of Caracalla it formed the ordinary circulating medium
in the eastern part of the empire, and several cities possessed the right of
coining silver in their local mints. Both the imperial and the local mints
often derived an illicit gain by diminishing the weight or debasing the purity
of the silver coins. Augustus, as has been already mentioned, coined 84 denarii from a pound of silver and Nero
96. Hadrian, though he made no change in the legal standard, permitted the mint
to issue silver coins of less than the standard purity, and many of his
successors imitated his bad example. The relative value of the aureus and the denarius underwent a change as soon as a considerable quantity of
the silver coinage, whether issued by the imperial or local mints, was of
debased metal, and aurei of standard
weight were sold by the money-changers at an agio. The emperors appear to have defrauded those they paid in
silver by issuing base denarii as well as cheated those they paid in gold by
counting out light aurei.
When Caracalla coined fifty aurei to the pound, he seems to have proposed restoring the relative value of the
gold and silver money. To do this it was necessary to issue a new silver coin
of which twenty-five should be equal to the new aureus. Instead of restoring the denarius to its true proportion in
weight and purity, he issued the larger piece, in which the emperor is
represented with a radiated crown, called argenteus.
These contain a considerable portion of alloy, and were minted at the rate of
sixty to a pound of the new silver standard. The proportion adopted by
Caracalla for the silver coinage was not observed. A deterioration is apparent
even during the reigns of Alexander Severus, Maximinus, and Gordianus Pius,
though these emperors evidently made some efforts to arrest the depreciation of
the ordinary circulating medium by large issues of copper sestertii of full weight. They appear to have hoped to sustain the
value of the silver currency by keeping up the value of the copper coin which
circulated as its fractions.
The proportion of alloy in the silver coinage was rapidly increased after
the time of Gordianus Pius, and at last Gallienus put an end to the silver
coinage by issuing plated money and copper pieces washed with tin as a
substitute for silver. Thus a base denarius of his latter years was of less
value than an as of the former part of his reign, which ought to have been its
sixteenth part.
Gallienus threw the whole coinage of the empire into confusion. He
repeatedly reduced the size of the aureus according to his temporary exigencies, but he preserved the standard purity of
the metal, for while he paid his own debts by tale he exacted payment of the
tribute of the provinces by weight. The intolerable oppression of his monetary
frauds and exactions, added to the disorder that prevailed in every branch of
the imperial government, goaded the provinces into rebellion. The rise of the
thirty tyrants, as the rebel emperors were called, must in some degree be
connected with the depreciation of the coinage, for the troops as well as the
provincials were sufferers by the frauds of his mint. The troops were ready to
support any emperor who would pay them a donative in coin of full weight, and
the provincials were ready to support any rebel who could resist the
transmission of the gold in the province to Rome.
The depreciation of the ordinary currency during the reign of Gallienus has
no parallel in history unless it be found in the recent depreciations of the
Othoman currency. Five hundred of the washed denarii or argentei of his latter coinage were required to purchase an aureus, while government compelled its
subjects to receive these base coins at the rate of twenty-five to an aureus.
The emperors defrauded their subjects, but the masters of the mint and the
corporation of moneyers shared the profits of these frauds, and rendered the
debasement of the coinage and the agio on gold a source of gain independent of the government. When Aurelian
endeavoured to restore the unity of the empire it was necessary for him to
re-establish uniformity in the currency. But when he attempted to reform the
abuses in the imperial mint, the masters of the mint and the corporation of
moneyers openly rebelled, and their power and numbers were so great that he is
said to have lost seven thousand men in suppressing their revolt.
The depreciation in the value of the circulating medium during the fifty
years between the reign of Caracalla and the death of Gallienus annihilated a
great part of the trading capital in the Roman Empire, and rendered it
impossible to carry on commercial transactions not only with foreign countries
but even with distant provinces. Every payment was liable to be greatly
diminished in real value, even when it was nominally the same. This state of
things at last induced capitalists to hoard their coins of pure gold and silver
for better days; and as these better days did not occur, all memory of many
hoards was lost, and the buried treasures, consisting of select coins, have
often remained concealed until the present time. Thus the frauds of the Roman
emperors have filled the cabinets of collectors and the national museums of
modem Europe with well-preserved coins.
The special effects of the depreciation of the Roman coinage on the wealth
of Greece cannot be traced in detail, for no facts are recorded by historians
which connect it prominently with any private or public event. The local mints
ceased to exist, when even their copper coins became of greater intrinsic value
than the money of the imperial mint of which they were nominally fractions. The as of the provincial city was more
valuable than the denarius of the
capital. Zosimus informs us that this monetary confusion produced commercial
anarchy, and it requires no historian to tell us that political anarchy is a
natural consequence of national bankruptcy. The laws which regulate the
distribution, the accumulation and the destruction of wealth, the demand for
labour and the gains of industry, attest that the depreciation of the currency
was one of the most powerful causes of the impoverishment and depopulation of
the Roman empire in the third century, and there can be no doubt that Greece
suffered severely from its operation.
Sect. VII
Depopulation of Greece caused by the Roman Government
Experience proves that the same law of the progress of society which gives
to an increasing population a tendency to outgrow the means of subsistence,
compels a declining one to press on the limits of taxation. A government may
push taxation up to that point when it arrests all increase in the means of
subsistence; but the moment this stationary condition of society is produced,
the people will begin to consume a portion of the wealth previously absorbed by
the public taxes, and the revenues of the country will have a tendency to
decrease; or, what is the same thing, in so far as the political law is
concerned, the government will find greater difficulty in collecting the same
amount of revenue, and, if it succeed, will cause a diminution in the
population.
The depopulation of the Roman provinces was, however, not caused entirely
by the financial oppression of the government. In order to secure new conquests
against rebellion, the armed population was generally exterminated, or reduced
to slavery. If the people displayed a spirit of independence, they were regarded
as robbers, and destroyed without mercy; and this cruelty was so engrafted into
the system of the Roman administration that Augustus treated the Salassi in
this manner, when their disorders could easily have been effectually prevented
by milder measures. At the time the Romans first engaged in war with the
Macedonians and Greeks, the contest was of so doubtful a nature that the Romans
were not likely to relax the usual policy which they adopted for weakening
their foes; Macedonia, Epirus, Aetolia, and Achaia, were therefore treated with
the greatest severity at the time of their conquest. Aemilius Paulus, in order
to secure the submission of Epirus, destroyed seventy cities, and sold one
hundred and fifty thousand of the inhabitants as slaves. The policy which
considered a reduction of the population necessary for securing obedience,
would not fail to adopt efficient measures to prevent its again becoming either
numerous or wealthy. The utter destruction of Carthage, and the extermination
of the Carthaginians, is a fact which has no parallel in the history of any
other civilized stated Mummius razed Corinth to the ground, and sold its whole
population as slaves. Delos was the great emporium of the trade of the East
about the time of the conquest of Greece; it was plundered by the troops of
Mithridates, and again by the orders of Sulla. It only recovered its former
state of prosperity under the Romans as a slave-market. Sulla utterly destroyed
several cities of Boeotia, and depopulated Athens, the Piraeus, and Thebes. The
inhabitants of Megara were nearly exterminated by Julius Caesar; and a
considerable number of cities in Achaia, Aetolia, and Acarnania, were laid
waste by order of Augustus, and their inhabitants were settled in the newly
established Roman colonies of Nicopolis and Patrae. Brutus levied five years’
tribute in advance from the inhabitants of Asia Minor. His severity made the
people of Xanthus prefer extermination to submission. Cassius, after he had
taken Rhodes, treated it in the most tyrannical manner, and displayed a truly
Roman spirit of fiscal rapacity. The celebrated letter of Sulpicius to Cicero,
so familiar to the lovers of poetry from the paraphrase of Lord Byron, affords
irrefragable testimony to the rapid decline of Greece under the Roman
government.
During the civil wars, the troops which Greece still possessed were
compelled to range themselves on one side or the other. The Aetolians and
Acarnanians joined Caesar; the Athenians, Lacedaemonians, and Boeotians, ranged
themselves as partisans of Pompey. The Athenians, and most of the other Greeks,
afterwards espoused the cause of Brutus and Cassius; but the Lacedaemonians
sent a body of two thousand men to serve as auxiliaries of Octavius. The
destruction of property caused by the progress through Greece of the various
bodies of troops, whose passions were inflamed by the disorders of the civil
war, was not compensated by the favours conferred on a few cities by Caesar,
Antony, and Augustus. The remission of a few taxes, or the present of
additional revenues to an oligarchical magistracy, could exercise no influence
on the general prosperity of the country.
The depopulation caused by war alone might have been very soon repaired,
had the government of Greece been wisely administered. But there are conditions
of society which render it difficult to replace capital or recruit population
when either of them has undergone any considerable diminution. Attica appears
never to have recovered from the ravages committed by Philip V of Macedon as early
as the year B.C. 200, when he burned down the buildings and groves of
Cynosarges and the Lyceum in the immediate vicinity of Athens, and the temples,
olive-trees, and vineyards over the whole country. The Athenians had even then
lost the social and moral energy necessary for repairing the damage produced by
a great national calamity. They could no longer pursue a life of agricultural
employment: their condition had degenerated into that of a mere city
population, and the thoughts and feelings of Greek freemen were those of a town
mob. In such circumstances the ravages of an enemy permanently diminished the
resources of the country, for in a land like Greece, ages of labour and the
accumulated savings of generations are required to cover the arid limestone
mountains with olive and fig trees, and to construct the cisterns and canals of
irrigation which are necessary to render a dry soil capable of yielding
abundant supplies of food. In Athens bad government, social corruption,
literary presumption, and national conceit, were nourished by liberal donations
from foreign princes, who repaid flattery by feeding a worthless city
population. Servility became more productive than honest industry, and the
depopulation which resulted from wars and revolutions continued when Greece
enjoyed peace under the domination of Rome. The statues of the gods erected in
temples which had fallen into ruins, sculptured dedications and marble tombs,
monuments of a wealthy and dense rural population of free citizens in the
agricultural demes of Attica, were seen in the times of Hadrian, as the
turbaned tombstone may now be seen in Turkey near the solitary desolation of
the ruined mosque, testifying the rapid depopulation and destruction of vested
capital which is now going on in the Othoman empire. A Roman writer says, that
in Attica there were more gods and heroes than living men. It is impossible to
point out, in precise detail, all the various measures by which the Roman
administration undermined the physical and moral strength of the Greek nation;
it is sufficient to establish the fact, that too much was exacted from the body
of the people in the shape of public burdens, and that the neglect of all its
duties on the part of the government gradually diminished the productive resources
of the country. Works of utility were neglected; bands of robbers were allowed
to infest the provinces for long periods without molestation. The extortions of
the Roman magistrates, however, were more injurious, and rendered property more
insecure, than the violence of the banditti. The public acts of robbery are
those only which have been preserved by history; but for each open attack on
public property, hundreds of private families were reduced to poverty, and
thousands of free Greeks sold as slaves. Fulvius despoiled the temples of
Ambracia of their most valuable ornaments, and even carried away the statues of
the gods. Verres, on his passage through Greece to his post in Cilicia, carried
off a quantity of gold from the temple of Minerva at Athens. Piso, while
proconsul of Macedonia, plundered both it and Greece, and allowed them to be
ravaged by Thracian banditti. Even under the cautious and conciliatory
administration of Augustus, the oppressive conduct of the Romans caused
seditions, both in Laconia — which was a favoured district, from its having
taken part with the emperor against Antony— and in Attica, where the weakness
to which the city was reduced seemed to render any expression of discontent
impossible. The Greeks had not, in the time of Augustus, entirely lost their
ancient spirit and valour, and though comparatively feeble, their conduct was
an object of some solicitude to the Roman government.
The moral causes of depopulation were perhaps even more powerful than the
political. They had been long in operation, and had produced great changes in
the Greek character before the Roman conquest; and as some similar social evils
were acting on the Romans themselves, the moral condition of Greece was not
improved by the Roman government. The most prevalent evil was a spirit of
self-indulgence and utter indifference to the duty of man in private life,
which made every rank averse to marriage, and unwilling to assume the
responsibility of educating a family. The Greeks never adorned the vestibules
of their houses with the statues and busts of their ancestors; their inordinate
self-conceit taught them to concentrate their admiration on themselves. And the
Romans, even with the family pride which led to this noble practice, were
constantly losing the glories of their race by conferring their name on adopted
scions of other houses. The religion, and often the philosophy, of the ancients
encouraged vicious indulgence, and the general rule of society in the first
century of the Roman Empire was to live with concubines selected from a class
of female slaves educated for this station. The land, which had formerly
maintained a thousand free citizens capable of marching to defend their country
as hoplites, was now regarded as affording a scanty provision for the household
of a single proprietor who considered himself too poor to marry. His estate was
cultivated by a tribe of slaves, while he amused himself with the music of the
theatre, or the equally idle sounds of the philosophic schools. The desire to
occupy larger properties than their ancestors had cultivated, has already been
noticed as an effect of the riches obtained by the Macedonian conquests; and
its influence as a moral check on the population of Greece has been adverted to.
This cause of depopulation increased under the Roman government. The love of
immense parks, splendid villas and luxurious living, fostered vice and celibacy
to such an extent in the higher ranks, that the wealthy families became
gradually extinct. The line of distinction between the rich and the poor was
constantly becoming more marked. The rich formed an aristocratic class, the
poor were sinking into a dependent grade in society; they were fast approaching
the state of coloni or serfs. In this
state of society, neither class shows a tendency to in- crease. It appears
indeed to be a law of human society, that all classes of mankind which are
separated, by superior wealth and privileges, from the body of the people, and
by their oligarchical constitution, liable to a rapid decline. As the
privileges which they enjoy have created an unnatural position in life, vice is
increased beyond that limit which is consistent with the duration of society.
The fact has been long observed with regard to the oligarchies of Sparta and
Rome. It had its effect even on the more extended citizenship of Athens, and it
even affected, in our times, the two hundred thousand electors who formed the
oligarchy of France during the reign of Louis Philippe.
Sect. VIII
Roman Colonies established in
Greece.
Two Roman colonies, Corinth and Patrae, were established in Greece. They
soon became the principal cities, and were for ages the centres of the
political administration. Their influence on Greek society was very great, yet
Latin continued to be the spoken language of the inhabitants, and their
institutions and local government remained exclusively Roman until the decree
of Caracalla extended the Roman franchise to all Greece.
The site of Corinth was devoted to the gods when Mummius destroyed the city
and exterminated its inhabitants. From that time it remained desolate until,
after an interval of more than a hundred years, Julius Caesar repeopled it with
a colony of Romans. The advantages of its position, its rich territory, its
impregnable citadel, its narrow isthmus, and its ports on two seas, made it
equally valuable as a military and naval station, and as a commercial mart.
Caesar refortified the Acro-Corinth, repaired the temples, rebuilt the city,
restored the ports, and established a numerous population of veteran
legionaries and industrious freedmen in the new city. Corinth became once more
flourishing and populous. Its colonial coinage from the time of Julius to that
of Gordian III is abundant, and often beautiful. It attests the extent of its
trade and the taste of its inhabitants. But the new Corinth was not a Greek
city. The mother of so many Hellenic colonies was now a foreign colony in
Hellas. Her institutions were Roman, her language was Latin, her manners were
tinctured with the lupine ferocity of the race of Romulus. Shows of gladiators
were the delight of her amphitheatre; and though she shed a strong light over
fallen Greece, it was only a lurid reflection of the splendour of Rome.
The position of Corinth was admirably suited for a military station to
overlook the proceedings of the Greeks who were opposed to Caesar’s government.
The measure was evidently one of precaution, and very little was done to give
it the show of having originated in a wish to revive the prosperity of Greece.
The population of the new Corinth was allowed to collect building materials,
and search for wealth, in any way, how offensive soever it might be to the
feelings of the Greeks. The tombs, which had alone escaped the fury of Mummius,
were destroyed to construct the new buildings, and excavated for the rich
ornaments and valuable sepulchral vases which they often contained. So
systematically did the Romans pursue this profession of violating the tombs,
that it became a source of very considerable wealth to the colony, and Rome was
filled with works of archaic art. The facilities which the position of Corinth
afforded for maritime communications, not only with every part of Greece, but
also with Italy and Asia Minor, rendered it the seat of the Roman provincial
administration, and the usual residence of the proconsul of Achaia.
The policy of Augustus towards Greece was openly one of precaution. The
Greeks still continued to occupy the attention of the ruling class at Rome,
more perhaps than their declining power warranted; they had not yet sunk into
the political insignificancy which they were destined to reach in the days of
Juvenal and Tacitus. Augustus reduced the power of all those Greek states that
retained any influence, whether they had joined his own party or favoured
Antony. Athens was deprived of its authority over Eretria and Aegina, and
forbidden to increase its local revenues by selling the right of citizenship.
Lacedaemon was also weakened by the establishment of the independent community
of the free Laconians, a confederation of twenty-four maritime cities, whose
population, consisting chiefly of perioikoi,
had hitherto paid taxes to Sparta. Augustus, it is true, assigned the island of
Cythera, and a few places on the Messenian frontier, to the Lacedaemonian
state; but the gift was a very slight compensation for the loss sustained in a
political point of view, whatever it might have been in a financial.
Augustus established a Roman colony at Patrae to extinguish the smouldering
nationality of Achaia, and to keep open a gate through which a Roman force
might at any time pour into Greece. Patrae then lay in ruins, and the
proprietors of its territory dwelt in the villages around. Augustus repaired
the city, and re-peopled it with Roman citizens, freedmen, and the veterans of
the twenty-second legion. To fill up the void in the numbers of the middle and
lower orders of the free population, necessary for the immediate formation of a
large city, the inhabitants of some neighbouring Greek towns were compelled to
abandon their dwellings and reside in Patrae. The local government of the
colony was endowed with municipal revenues taken from several Achaean and
Locrian cities which were deprived of their civic existence. Patrae was often
the residence of the proconsul of Achaia, and it flourished for ages both as a
Roman administrative station and as a port possessing great commercial
resources. Its colonial coinage, though neither so abundant nor so elegant in
its fabric as that of Corinth, extends from the time of Augustus to that of
Gordian III. As in all Roman colonies, the political institutions of Rome were
closely imitated at Corinth and Patrae. Their highest magistrates were
duumviri, who represented the consulate, and who were annually elected; or,
perhaps, it would be more correct to say, were selected for a nominal election
by the imperial authorities. Other magistrates were elected, and some were
appointed to perform those duties in the colonies which were similar to the
functions of the great office-bearers in Rome. And as the model of the Roman
government was originally that of a single city, the resemblance was easily maintained.
Under the emperors, however, the colonies gradually sank into ordinary
corporations for the transaction of administrative and fiscal business, under
the immediate control of the Roman proconsuls and provincial governors.
Augustus also founded a new city called Nicopolis, to commemorate the
victory of Actium, but it was as much a triumphal monument as a political
establishment. Its organization was that of a Greek city, not of a Roman
colony; and its quinquennial festival of the Actia was instituted on the model
of the great games of Greece, and placed under the superintendence of the
Lacedaemonians. Its population consisted of Greeks who were compelled to desert
their native cities in Epirus, Acarnania, and Aetolia. Its territory was
extensive, and it was admitted into the Amphictyonic council as a Greek state.
The manner in which Augustus peopled Nicopolis proves his indifference to the
feelings of humanity, and the imperfection of his knowledge in that political
science which enables a statesman to convert a small territory into a
flourishing State.
The principles of his colonization contributed as directly to the decline
and depopulation of Italy and Greece, as the accidental tyranny or folly of any
of his successors. The inhabitants of a great part of Aetolia were torn from
their abodes, where they were residing on their own property, surrounded by
their cattle, their olive-trees and vineyards, and compelled to construct such
dwellings as they were able, and find such means of livelihood as presented
themselves, at Nicopolis. The destruction of an immense amount of vested
capital in provincial buildings was the consequence; the agriculture of a whole
province was ruined, and a considerable agricultural population must have pined
in poverty or perished from want in the changed circumstances of a city life.
Nicopolis long continued to be the principal city in Epirus. Its local coinage
extends from Augustus down to the reign of Gallienus. The legends are Greek,
and the fabric rude. The peculiar privileges conferred on the three colonies of
Corinth, Patrae, and Nicopolis, and the close connection in which they were
placed with the imperial government, enabled them to flourish for centuries
amidst the general poverty which the despotic system of the Roman provincial
administration spread over the rest of Greece.
Sect. IX
Political Condition of Greece from the time of Augustus to that of
Caracalla.
Two descriptions of Greece have been preserved, which afford vivid pictures
of the impoverished condition of the country during two centuries of the Roman
government. Strabo has left us an account of the aspect of Greece, shortly
after the foundation of the colonies of Patrae and Nicopolis. Pausanias has
described, with melancholy exactness, the desolate appearance of many
celebrated cities, during the time of the Antonines. Governors and proconsuls
were sent to administer the government who were ignorant of the Greek language.
The taxes imposed on the country, and the expenses of the provincial
administration, drained off all the wealth of the people; and those necessary
public works, which required a large expenditure for their maintenance and
preservation, were allowed to fall gradually into ruin. The emperors, at times,
indeed, attempted, by a few isolated acts of mercy, to alleviate the sufferings
of the Greeks. Tiberius, as we have already mentioned, united the provinces of
Achaia and Macedonia to the imperial government of Moesia, in order to deliver
them from the weight of the proconsular administration. His successor restored
them to the senate. When Nero visited Greece to receive a crown at the Olympic
Games, he recompensed the Greeks for their flatteries by declaring them free
from tribute. The immunities which he conferred produced some serious disputes
be- tween the various states, concerning the collection of their municipal
taxes; and Vespasian rendered these disputes a pretext for annulling the
freedom conferred by Nero. The free cities of Greece still possessed not only
the administration of considerable revenues, but also the power of raising
money, by local taxes, for the maintenance of their temples, schools,
universities, aqueducts, roads, ports, and public buildings. Trajan carefully
avoided destroying any of the municipal privileges of the Greeks, and he
endeavoured to improve their condition by his just and equitable
administration; yet his policy was adverse to the increase of local
institutions.
Hadrian opened a new line of policy to the sovereigns of Rome, and avowed
the determination of reforming the institutions of the Romans, and adapting his
government to the altered state of society in the empire. He perceived that the
central government was weakening its power, and diminishing its resources, by
acts of injustice, which rendered property everywhere insecure. He remedied the
evils which resulted from the irregular dispensation of the laws by the
provincial governors, and effected reforms which certainly exercised a
favourable influence on the condition of the inhabitants of the provinces. His
reign laid the foundation of that regular and systematic administration of
justice in the Roman empire, which gradually absorbed all the local judicatures
of the Greeks, and, by forming a numerous and well-educated society of lawyers,
guided by uniform rules, raised up a partial barrier against arbitrary power.
In order to lighten the weight of taxation, Hadrian abandoned all the arrears
of taxes accumulated in preceding years. His general system of administrative
reforms was pursued by the Antonines, and perfected by the edict of Caracalla,
which conferred the rank of Roman citizens on all the free inhabitants of the
empire. Hadrian certainly deserves the merit of having first seen the necessity
of securing the imperial government, by effacing all badges of servitude from
the provincials, and connecting the interests of the landed proprietors
throughout the Roman empire with the existence of the imperial administration.
He secured to the provincials that legal rank in the constitution of the empire
which placed their rights on a level with those of Roman citizens, and for this
he was hated by the senate.
Hadrian, from personal taste, cultivated Greek literature, and admired
Grecian art. He left traces of his love of improvement in every portion of the
empire, through which he kept constantly travelling; but Greece, and especially
Attica, received an extraordinary share of the imperial favour. It is difficult
to estimate how far his conduct immediately affected the general well-being of
the population, or to point out the precise manner of its operation on society;
but it is evident that the impulse given to improvement by his example and his
administration, produced some tendency to ameliorate the condition of the
Greeks. Greece had, perhaps, sunk to its lowest state of poverty and
depopulation under the financial administration of the Flavian family, and it
displayed many signs of reviving prosperity, while it enjoyed the advantage of
good government under Hadrian. The extraordinary improvements which the Roman
emperors might have effected, by a judicious employment of the public revenues,
may be estimated from the immense public works executed by Hadrian. At Athens
he completed the temple of Jupiter Olympius, which had been commenced by
Pisistratus, and of which sixteen columns still exist to astonish the spectator
by their size and beauty. He built temples to Juno and to Jupiter Panhellenius,
and ornamented the city with a magnificent pantheon, a library, and a
gymnasium. He commenced an aqueduct to convey an abundant stream of water from
Cephisia, which was completed by Antoninus. At Megara, he rebuilt the temple of
Apollo. He constructed an aqueduct which conveyed the waters of the lake
Stymphalus to Corinth, and he erected new baths in that city. But the surest
proof that his improvements were directed by a judicious spirit is to be found
in his attention to the roads. Nothing could tend more to advance the
prosperity of this, mountainous country than removing the difficulties of
intercourse between its various provinces; for there is no country where the
expense of transport presents a greater barrier to trade, or where the
obstacles to internal communication form a more serious impediment to
improvement in the social condition of the agricultural population. He rendered
the road from Northern Greece to the Peloponnesus, by the Scironian rocks, easy
and commodious for wheeled carriages. Great, however, as these improvements
were, he conferred one still greater on the Greeks, as a nation, by commencing
the task of moulding their various local customs and laws into one general
system, founded on the basis of Roman jurisprudence; and while he ingrafted the
law of the Romans on the stock of society in Greece, he did not seek to destroy
the municipal institutions of the people. The policy of Hadrian, in raising the
Greeks to an equality of civil rights with the Romans, sanctioned whatever
remained of the Macedonian institutions throughout the East; and as soon as the
edict of Caracalla had conferred on all the subjects of the empire the rights
of Roman citizenship, the Greeks became, in reality, the dominant people in the
Eastern portion of the empire, and Greek institutions ultimately ruled society
under the supremacy of Roman law.
It is curious that Antoninus, who adopted all the views of Hadrian with
regard to the annihilation of the exclusive supremacy of the Roman citizens,
should have thought it worth his attention to point out the supposed ancient
connection between Rome and Arcadia. He was the first Roman who commemorated
this fanciful relationship between Greece and Rome by any public act. He
conferred on Pallantium, the Arcadian city from which Evander was supposed to
have led a Greek colony to the banks of the Tiber, all the privileges ever
granted to the most favoured municipalities in the Roman Empire. The habits and
character of Marcus Aurelius led him to regard the Greeks with the greatest
favour; and had his reign been more peaceful, and left his time more at his own
disposal, the sophists and philosophers of Greece would, in all probability,
have profited by his leisure. He rebuilt the temple of Eleusis, which had been
burnt to the ground; he improved the schools of Athens, and increased the
salaries of the professors, who then rendered that city the most celebrated
university in the civilized world. Herodes Atticus, whose splendid public
edifices in Greece rivalled the works of Hadrian, gained great influence by his
eminence in literature and taste, as well as by his enormous wealth. It was the
golden age of rhetoricians, whose services were rewarded not only with liberal
salaries and donations in money, but even with such magisterial authority and
honour as the Greek cities could confer. Herodes Atticus had been selected by
Antoninus Pius to give lessons in eloquence to Marcus Aurelius and Lucius
Verus, and he was treated with distinction by Marcus Aurelius, until it was
necessary to reprove his oppressive and tyrannical conduct to the Athenians.
The friendship of the emperor did not save him from disgrace, though his
freedmen alone were punished.
Little can be collected concerning the condition of Greece under the
successors of Marcus Aurelius. The Roman government was occupied with wars,
which seldom directly affected the provinces occupied by the Greeks. Literature
and science were little regarded by the soldiers of fortune who mounted the
imperial throne; and Greece, forgotten and neglected, appears to have enjoyed a
degree of tranquillity and repose, which enabled her to profit by the
improvements in the imperial government which Hadrian had introduced and the
decree of Caracalla had ratified.
The institutions of the Greeks, which were unconnected with the exercise of
the supreme executive power, were generally allowed to exist, even by the most
jealous of the emperors. When these institutions disappeared, their destruction
was effected by the progressive change which time gradually introduced into
Greek society, and not by any violence on the part of the Roman government. It
is difficult, indeed, to trace the limits of the state and city administration
in matters of taxation, or the exact extent of their control over their local
funds. Some cities possessed independence, and others were free from tribute;
and these privileges gave the Greek nation a political position in the empire,
which prevented their being confounded with the other provincials in the East,
until the reign of Justinian. As the Greek cities in Thrace, Asia Minor, Syria,
and Egypt preserved these important privileges, it is not wonderful that, in
Greece, the whole frame of the ancient social institutions was preserved.
Pausanias found the Amphictyonic council still holding its meetings, three
centuries after the Roman conquest. The deputies of the Achaean, Boeotian, and
Phocic commonwealths continued to meet for the purpose of transacting the
business of their confederacies. The Athenians were allowed to maintain an
armed guard in the island of Delos. The Olympic, Pythic, and Isthmian games
were regularly celebrated. The Areopagus at Athens, and the Gerontia at Sparta,
still exercised their functions. The different cities and provinces affected
the use of their peculiar dialects, and the inhabitants of Sparta continued to
imitate the Laconism of antiquity in their public despatches, though their
altered manners rendered it ridiculous. The mountaineers of Attica, in the time
of Antoninus, spoke a purer language than the populace of the city of Athens,
which still bore evidence of its heterogeneous origin after the massacre of
Sulla. Had the financial burdens of the Roman government not weighed too
heavily on the population, the rivalry of the Greeks, actively directed to
local improvements and to commerce, instead of being too exclusively and
ostentatiously devoted to philosophy, literature, and the arts, might have
proved more useful and honourable to their country. But the moral supports of
the old framework of society were destroyed before the edict of Caracalla had
emancipated Greece; and when tranquillity arrived, they were only capable of
enjoying the felicity of having been forgotten by their tyrants.
Sect. X.
The Greeks and Romans never showed any disposition to unite and form one
people.
The habits and tastes of the Greeks and Romans were so different, that
their familiar intercourse produced a feeling of antipathy in the two nations.
The Roman writers, from prejudice and jealousy, of which they were themselves,
perhaps, unconscious, have transmitted to us a very incorrect picture of the
state of the Greeks during the first centuries of the empire. They did not
observe, with attention, the marked distinction between the Asiatic and
Alexandrine Greeks and the natives of Hellas. The European population, pursuing
the quiet life of landed proprietors, or engaged in the pursuits of commerce
and agriculture, was considered, by Roman prejudice, as unworthy of notice.
Lucian, himself a Greek, indeed contrasts the tranquil and respectable manner
of life at Athens with the folly and luxury of Rome; but the Romans looked on
provincials as little better than serfs (coloni)
and merchants were, in their eyes, only tolerated cheats. The Greek character
was estimated from the conduct of the adventurers, who thronged from the
wealthy and corrupted cities of the East to seek their fortunes at Rome, and
who, from motives of fashion and taste, were unduly favoured by the wealthy
aristocracy. The most distinguished of these Greeks were literary men,
professors of philosophy, rhetoric, grammar, mathematics, and music. Great
numbers were engaged as private teachers; and this class was regarded with some
respect by the Roman nobility, from its intimate connection with their
families. The great mass of the Greeks residing at Rome were, however, employed
in connection with the public and private amusements of the capital, and were
found engaged in every profession, from the directors of the theatres and
opera-houses, down to the swindlers who frequented the haunts of vice. The
testimony of the Latin authors may be received as sufficiently accurate
concerning the light in which the Greeks were regarded at Rome, and as a not
incorrect portraiture of the Greek population of the capital.
The expressions of the Romans, when speaking of the Greeks, often display
nothing more than the manner in which the proud aristocracy of the empire
regarded all foreigners, those even whom they admitted to their personal
intimacy. The Greeks were confounded with the great body of strangers from the
Eastern nations, in one general sentence of condemnation; and not unnaturally,
for the Greek language served as the ordinary means of communication with all
foreigners from the East. The magicians, conjurers, and astrologers of Syria,
Egypt, and Chaldea, were naturally mixed up, both in society and public opinion,
with the adventurers of Greece, and contributed to form the despicable type
which was unjustly enough transferred from the fortune-hunters at Rome to the
whole Greek nation. It is hardly necessary to observe that Greek literature, as
cultivated at Rome during this period, had no connection with the national
feelings of the Greek people. As far as the Greeks themselves were concerned,
learning was an honourable and lucrative occupation to its successful
professors; but in the estimation of the higher classes at Rome, Greek
literature was merely an ornamental exercise of the mind,— a fashion of the
wealthy. This ignorance of Greece and the Greeks induced Juvenal to draw his
conclusive proof of the utter falsity of the Greek character, and of the fabulous
nature of all Greek history, from his own doubts concerning a fact which is
avouched by the testimony of Herodotus and Thucydides; but as a retort to the Graecia mendax of the Roman satirist,
the observation of Lucian may be cited — that the Romans spoke truth only once
in their lives, and that was when they made their wills.
The Greeks repaid the scorn of the Romans with greater and not more
reasonable contempt. When the two nations first came into collision, the Romans
were certainly far less polished than the Greeks, though they were much
superior to them in virtue and courage. They acknowledged their inferiority,
and readily derived lessons of instruction from a people unable to resist their
arms. The obligation was always recognised. And Roman gratitude inflated Greek
vanity to such a degree, that the conquered never perceived that their masters
became at last as much their superiors in literary genius as in political and
military science. The Greeks seem always to have remained ignorant that there were
Roman writers whose works would, by successive generations and distant nations,
be placed almost in the same rank as their own classic authors. The rhetorical
contemporaries of Tacitus and of Juvenal never suspected that the original
genius of those writers had extended the domain of literature, nor could any
critic have persuaded them that Horace had already surpassed the popularity of
their own poets by a graceful union of social elegance with calm sagacity.
A single example of the supercilious egoism of the Greeks will be
sufficient to show the extent of their presumption during their political
degradation as Roman provincials. When Apollonius of Tyana, the pythagorean
philosopher, who excited the admiration of the Hellenic world during the first
century, visited Smyrna, he was invited to attend the Panionian Assembly. On
reading the decree of the council, he observed that it was signed by men who
had adopted Roman names, and he immediately addressed a letter to the
Panionians blaming their barbarism. He reproached them for laying aside the
names of their ancestors, for quitting the names of heroes and legislators to
assume such names as Lucullus and Fabricius. Now, when we remember that this
rebuke was gravely uttered by a native of the Cappadocian city of Tyana, to a
corporation of degenerate Asiatic Greeks, it forms a curious monument of the
delusions of national vanity.
The Romans were never very deeply imbued with a passionate admiration for
Grecian art, with which every rank in Greece was animated. The national pride
and personal vanity of the conquerors, it is true, often coveted the possession
of the most celebrated works of art, which were transported to Rome as much on
account of their celebrity as their merit, for the painting and sculpture which
they could procure as articles of commercial industry were sufficient to
gratify Roman taste. This was peculiarly fortunate for Greece, since there can
be no doubt that, if the Romans had been as enthusiastic lovers of art as they
were indefatigable hunters after riches, they would not have hesitated to
regard all those works of art, which were the public property of the Grecian
states, as belonging to the Roman commonwealth by the right of conquest. It was
only because the avarice of the people would have received little gratification
from the seizure, that Greece was allowed to retain her statues and paintings
when she was plundered of her gold and silver. The great dissimilarity of
manners between the two nations appears in the aversion with which many
distinguished senators viewed the introduction of the works of Grecian art by
Marcellus and Mummius, after the conquests of Syracuse and Corinth. This
aversion unquestionably contributed much to save Greece from the general
confiscation of her treasures of art, to which her people clung with the most
passionate attachment. Cicero says that no Greek city would consent to sell a
painting, a statue, or a work of art, but that, on the contrary, all were ready
to become purchasers. The inhabitants of Pergamus resisted the attempt of
Acratus, a commissioner sent by Nero, to carry off the most celebrated works of
art from the cities of Asia. The feeling of art, in the two peoples, is not
inaptly illustrated, by comparing the conduct of the Rhodian republic with that
of the Emperor Augustus. When the Rhodians were besieged by Demetrius
Poliorcetes, they refused to destroy his statues, and those of his father,
which had been erected in their agora. But when Augustus conquered Egypt he
ordered all the statues of Antony to be destroyed, and, with a meanness
somewhat at variance with patrician dignity, he accepted a bribe of one
thousand talents from the Alexandrines to spare the statues of Cleopatra. The
Greeks honoured art even more than the Romans loved vengeance. Works of art
were carried away by those Roman governors who spared nothing they could
pillage in their provinces; but these spoliations were always regarded in the
light of direct robberies; and Fulvius Nobilior, Verres, and Piso, who
distinguished themselves in this species of violence, were considered as the
most infamous of the Roman magistrates.
It is true that Sulla carried off the ivory statue of Minerva from the
temple of Alalcomenae, and that Augustus removed that of the great temple of
Tegea, as a punishment because that city espoused the party of Antony. But
these very exceptions prove how sparingly the Romans availed themselves of
their rights of conquest; or history would have recorded the remarkable statues
which they had allowed to remain in Greece, rather than signalized as
exceptions the few which they transported to Rome. When Caligula and Nero were
permitted to govern the world according to the impulses of insanity, they
ordered many celebrated works of art to be conveyed to Rome — among these, the
celebrated Cupid of Praxiteles was twice removed. It was restored to Thespiae
by Claudius; but, on being again taken away by Nero, it perished in a
conflagration. After the great conflagration at Rome, in which innumerable
works of art perished, Nero transported five hundred brazen statues from
Delphi, to adorn the capital and replace the loss it had suffered, and he
ordered all the cities of Greece and Asia Minor to be systematically plundered.
Very little is subsequently recorded concerning this species of plunder, which
Hadrian and his two immediate successors would hardly have permitted. From the
great number of the most celebrated works of ancient art which Pausanias
enumerates in his tour through Greece, it is evident that no extensive injury
had then occurred, even to the oldest buildings. After the reign of Commodus,
the Roman emperors paid but little attention to art; and unless the value of
the materials caused the destruction of ancient works, they were allowed to
stand undisturbed until the buildings around them crumbled into dust. During
the period of nearly a century which elapsed from the time of Pausanias until
the first irruption of the Goths into Greece, it is certain that the temples
and public buildings of the inhabited cities were very little changed in their
general aspect, from the appearance which they had presented when the Roman
legions first entered Hellas.
Sect. XI
State of Society among the Greeks
To give a complete account of the state of society among the Greeks under
the Roman Empire, it would be necessary to enter into many details concerning
the social and political institutions of the Romans, for both exercised great
influence in Greece. To avoid so extensive a field, it will be necessary to
give only a cursory sketch of those social peculiarities whose influence,
though apparent in the annals of the Roman Empire, did not permanently affect
the political history of the empire. The state of civilization, the popular
objects of pursuit, even the views of national advancement, continued, under
the imperial government, to be very different, and often opposite, in different
divisions of the Greek nation.
The inhabitants of Hellas had sunk into a quiet and secluded population.
The schools of Athens were still famous, and Greece was visited by numbers of
fashionable and learned travellers from other countries, as Italy now is; but
the citizens dwelt in their own little world, clinging to antiquated forms and
usages, and to old superstitions, — holding little intercourse, and having
little community of feeling, either with the rest of the empire or with the
other divisions of the Hellenic race.
The maritime cities of Europe, Asia Minor, and the Archipelago contained a
considerable population, chiefly occupied in commerce and manufactures, and
taking little interest in the politics of Rome, or in the literature of Greece.
Though the Greeks looked on trade with more favour than the Romans, declining
wealth and unjust laws were rapidly tending to depreciate the mercantile
character, and to render the occupation less respectable, even in the
commercial cities. It is not inappropriate to notice one instance of Roman
commercial legislation. Julius Caesar, among his projects of reform, thought fit
to revive an old Roman law, which prohibited any citizen from having in his
possession a larger sum than sixty thousand sesterces in the precious metals.
This law was, of course, neglected; but under Tiberius it was made a pretext by
informers to levy various fines and confiscations in Greece and Syria. The
commerce of the eastern part of the Mediterranean which had once consisted of
commodities of general consumption, declined, under the fiscal avarice of the
Romans, into an export trade of some articles of luxury to the larger cities of
the west of Europe. The wines of the Archipelago, the carpets of Pergamus, the
cambric of Cos, and the dyed woollens of Laconia, are particularly mentioned.
The decrease of trade is not to be overlooked as one of the causes of the
decline and depopulation of the Roman Empire; for wealth depended even more on
commerce in ancient times, than it does in modern, on account of the imperfect
means of transport, and the impolitic laws relating to the exportation of grain
from many provinces to Rome, where its gratuitous distribution to a large part
of the population, and its frequent sale below the cost of production in Italy
deranged all commercial operations.
The division of the Greek nation which occupied the most important social
position in the empire, consisted of the remains of the Macedonian and Greek
colonies in Asia Minor, Egypt, and Syria. These countries were filled with
Greeks; and the cities of Alexandria and Antioch, the second and third in the
empire in size, population, and wealth, were chiefly peopled by Greeks. The
influence of Alexandria alone on the Roman Empire, and on European
civilization, would require a treatise, in order to do justice to the subject.
Its schools of philosophy produced modifications of Christianity in the East,
and attempted to infuse a new life into the torpid members of paganism by means
of gnosticism and neoplatonism. The feuds between the Jews and Christians,
which arose out of its local quarrels, were bequeathed to following centuries;
and in Western Europe, we still debase Christianity by the admixture of those
prejudices which had their rise in the amphitheatre of Alexandria. Its wealth
and population excited the jealousy of Augustus, who deprived it of its
municipal institutions, and rendered it a prey to the factions of the
amphitheatre, the curse of Roman civic anarchy. The populace, unrestrained by
any system of order founded on corporate institutions, and without any social
guidance derived from any acknowledged municipal authority, was abandoned to
the passions of the wildest democracy, whenever they were crowded together.
Hadrian was struck with the activity and industry of the Alexandrines; and
though he does not appear to have admired their character, he saw that the
increase of privileges to some organized classes of the population was the true
way to lessen the influence of the mob.
Antioch and the other Greek cities of the East preserved their municipal
privileges; and the Greek population in Asia Minor, Egypt, and Syria, remained
everywhere completely separated from the original inhabitants. Their corporate
organization often afforded them an opportunity of interfering with the details
of the public administration, and their intriguing and seditious spirit enabled
them to defend their rights and interests. When the free population of the
provinces acquired the rights of Roman citizenship, the Greeks of these
countries, who formed the majority of the privileged classes, and were already
in possession of the principal share of the local administration, became soon
possessed of the whole authority of the Roman government. They appeared as the
real representatives of the State, excluded the native population from power,
and, consequently, rendered it more dissatisfied than formerly. In the East,
therefore, after the publication of Caracalla’s edict, the Greeks became again
the dominant people, as they had been before the Roman conquest. In spite of
the equality of all the provincials in the eye of the law, a violent opposition
was created between them and the native population in Syria, Egypt, and a large
part of Asia Minor, where various nations still retained their own customs and
languages. The Greeks, in a large portion of the eastern half of the empire,
occupied a position nearly similar to that of the Romans in the western. The
same causes produced similar effects, and from the period when the Greeks
became a privileged and dominant class, administering the severe fiscal
supremacy of the Roman government, instead of ruling with the more tolerant
habits of their Macedonian predecessors, their numbers and influence began to
decline. Like the Romans of Italy, Gaul, and Spain, the Greeks of Egypt, Syria,
and Mesopotamia destroyed themselves, perishing from the corruption which they
engendered by the abuse of their power.
The secluded position of the inhabitants of ancient Hellas almost conceals
their social condition from the view of the political historian. The principal
causes of the decline of Greece have been already explained; but the tone of
society, and the manner of living adopted by the upper and middle ranks,
accelerated the progress of national decay. It has been already remarked, that
the increase of wealth consequent on the Macedonian conquests had tended to
augment the size of private properties, and to add to the numbers of slaves in
Greece. Under the Romans, the general riches of the country were indeed very
much diminished; but individuals were enabled to acquire fortunes greater than
had been possessed by the ancient monarchs, and to possess estates larger than
the territories of many celebrated republics. Julius Eurycles owned a province,
and Herodes Atticus could have purchased a kingdom. While a few individuals
could amass unbounded wealth, the bulk of the people were prevented from
acquiring even a moderate independency; and when Plutarch says that Greece, in
his time, could not arm more than three thousand hoplitae, though the small states of Sicyon and Megara each
furnished that number at the battle of Plataea, it is necessary to remember the
change which had taken place in the size of private properties, as well as the
altered state of society, for both tended to diminish the numbers of the free
population. The taxes of Greece were remitted to Rome, and expended beyond the
limits of the province. The most useful public works were neglected, except
when a benevolent emperor like Hadrian, or a wealthy individual like Herodes
Atticus, thought fit to direct some portion of their expenditure to what was
useful as well as ornamental. Under a continuance of such circumstances, Greece
was drained of money and capital.
The poverty of Greece was farther increased by the gradual rise in the
value of the precious metals, — an evil which began to be generally felt about
the time of Nero, and which affected Greece with great severity, from the
altered distribution of wealth in the country, and the loss of its foreign
commerce, Greece had once been rich in mines, which had been a source of wealth
and prosperity to Siphnos and Athens, and had laid the foundation of the power
of Philip of Macedon. Gold and silver mines, when their produce is regarded as
articles of commerce, are a surer basis of wealth than mines of lead and
copper. The evils which have arisen in countries where gold and silver have
been produced, have proceeded from the fiscal regulations of the government.
The fiscal measures of the Romans soon rendered it a ruinous speculation for
private individuals to attempt working mines of the precious metals, and, in
the hands of the State, they soon proved unprofitable. Many mines were
exhausted; and even though the value of the precious metals was enhanced, some,
beyond the influence of the Roman power, were abandoned from those causes
which, after the second century of the Christian era, produced a sensible
diminution in the commercial transactions of the old hemisphere.
Greece suffered in the general decay; her commerce and manufactures, being
confined to supplying the consumption of a diminished and impoverished population,
sank into insignificancy. In a declining state of society, where political,
financial, and commercial causes combine to diminish the wealth of a nation, it
is difficult for individuals to alter their manner of life, and to restrict
their expenditure, with the promptitude necessary to escape impoverishment. It
is indeed seldom in their power to estimate the progress of the decay; and a
reasonable jointure, or a necessary mortgage, may ruin a family.
In this declining state of society, complaints of excessive luxury are
generally prevalent, and the Greek writers of the second century are filled
with lamentations on this subject. Such complaints alone do not prove that the
majority of the higher classes were living in a manner injurious to society,
either from their effeminacy or vicious expenditure. They only show that the
greater part of the incomes of private persons was consumed by their personal
expenditure; and that a due proportion was not set apart for creating new
productive property, in order to replace the deterioration, which time is ever
causing in that which already exists. People of property, when their annual
incomes proved insufficient for their personal expenditure, began to borrow
money, instead of trying to diminish their expenses. An accumulation of debts
became general throughout the country, and formed a great evil in the time of
Plutarch. These debts were partly caused by the oppression of the Roman
government, and by the chicanery of the fiscal officers, always pressing for
ready money, and were generally contracted to Roman money-lenders. It was in
this way that the Roman administration produced its most injurious effects in
the provinces, by affording to capitalists the means of accumulating enormous
wealth, and by forcing the proprietors of land into abject poverty. The
property of Greek debtors was at last transferred, to a very great extent, to
their Roman creditors. This transference, which, in a homogeneous society,
might have invigorated the upper classes, by substituting an industrious
timocracy for an idle aristocracy, had a very different effect. It introduced
new feelings of rivalry and extravagance, by filling the country with foreign
landlords. The Greeks could not long' maintain the struggle, and they sank
gradually lower and lower in wealth, until their poverty introduced an altered
state of society, and taught them the prudential and industrious habits of
farmers, in which tranquil position they escape, not only from the eye of
history, but even from antiquarian research.
It is difficult to convey a correct notion of the evils and demoralization
produced by private debts in the ancient world, though they often appear as one
of the most powerful agents in political revolutions, and were a constant
subject of attention to the statesman, the lawgiver, and the political
philosopher. Modern society has completely annihilated their political effects.
The greater facilities afforded to the transference of landed property, and the
ease with which capital now circulates, have given an extension to the
operations of banking which has remedied this peculiar defect in society. It
must be noticed, too, that the ancients regarded landed property as the
accessory of the citizen, even when its amount determined his rank in the
commonwealth: but the moderns view the proprietor as the accessory of the
landed property; and the political franchise, being inherent in the estate, is
lost by the citizen who alienates his property.
In closing this view of the state of the Greek people under the imperial
government, if is impossible not to feel that Greece cannot be included in the
general assertion of Gibbon, that if a man were called to fix the period in the
history of the world during which the condition of the human race was most
happy and prosperous, he would, without hesitation, name that which elapsed
from the death of Domitian to the accession of Commodus. It may be doubted
whether the Roman government ever relaxed the systematic oppression under which
the agricultural and commercial population of its provinces groaned; and even
Hadrian himself can hardly claim greater merit than that of having humanely
administered a system radically bad, and endeavoured to correct its most
prominent features of injustice. Greece, indeed, reached its lowest degree of
misery and depopulation about the time of Vespasian; but still there is ample
testimony in the pages of contemporary writers, to prove that the desolate
state of the country was not materially improved for a long period, and that
only partial signs of amelioration were apparent in the period so much vaunted
by Gibbon. The liberality of Hadrian, and the munificence of Herodes Atticus,
were isolated examples, and could not change the constitution of Rome. Many
splendid edifices of antiquity were repaired by these two benefactors of
Greece, but many works of public utility remained neglected on account of the
poverty of the diminished population of the country ; and most of the works of
Hadrian and Herodes Atticus contributed little more to the well-being of the
people than the wages of the labour expended on their construction. The roads
and aqueducts of Hadrian are wise exceptions, —as they diminished the expenses
of transport, and afforded increased facilities for production. Still the
sumptuous edifices, of which remains still exist, indicate that the object of
building was the erection of magnificent monuments of art— to commemorate the
taste and splendour of the founder, not to increase the resources of the land
or improve the condition of the industrious classes.
The condition of a declining population by no means implies that any
portion of the people is actually suffering from want of the necessaries of
life. A sudden change in the direction of commerce, and a considerable decrease
in the demand for the productions of manufacturing industry, must indeed, at
the time when such events occur, deprive numbers of their usual means of
subsistence, and create great misery, before the population suffers the
ultimate diminution which these causes necessitate. Such events may occur in an
improving as well as in a declining society. But, when the bulk of a country’s
productions is drawn from its own soil, and consumed by its own inhabitants,
the population may be in a declining condition, without the circumstance being
suspected for some time, either at home or abroad. The chief cause of the
deterioration of the national resources will then arise from the members of
society consuming too great a proportion of their annual income, without
dedicating a due portion of their revenues to reproduction; in short, from
expending their incomes, without creating new sources of wealth, or taking any
measures to prevent the diminution of the old. Greece suffered from all the
causes alluded to; her commerce and manufactures were transferred to other
lands; and, when the change was completed, her inhabitants resolved to enjoy
life, instead of labouring to replace the wealth which their country had lost.
This diminution in the wealth of the people ultimately produced changes in
society, which laid the foundation for a great step in the improvement of the
human species. Poverty rendered slavery less frequent, and destroyed many of
the channels by which the slave trade had flourished. The condition of the
slaves also underwent several modifications, as the barrier between the slave
and the citizen was broken down by the necessity in which the poor classes of
freemen were placed of working at the same employments as slaves in order to
obtain the means of subsistence. At this favourable conjuncture Christianity
stepped in, to prevent avarice from ever recovering the ground which humanity
had gained.
Under oppressive governments, the person sometimes becomes more insecure
than property. This appears to have been the case under the Roman, as it has
since been under the Turkish government; and the population, in such case,
decreases much more rapidly than property is destroyed. The inhabitants of
Greece under the Roman Empire found themselves possessed of buildings, gardens,
vineyards, olive plantations, and all the agricultural produce which the
accumulated capital of former ages had created, to an extent capable of
maintaining a far more numerous population. The want of commerce, neglected
roads, the rarity of the precious metals in circulation, and the difficulties
thrown in the way of petty traffic by injudicious legislation, rendered the
surplus produce of each separate district of little value. The inhabitants
enjoyed the mere necessaries of life, and some of the luxuries of their
climate, in great abundance; but when they sought to purchase the productions
of art and foreign commerce, they felt themselves to be poor. Such a state of
society inevitably introduces a system of wasting what is superfluous, and of
neglecting to prepare new means of future production. In this condition of
indifference and ease the population of Greece remained, until the weakness of
the Roman government, the disorders of the army, and the diminution and
disarming of the free population, opened a way for the northern nations into
the heart of the empire.
Sect. XII
Influence of Religion and Philosophy on Society
The earliest records of the Greeks represent them as living completely free
from the despotic authority of a priestly class. The natural consequence of
this freedom was an indefinite latitude in the dogmas of the national faith:
and the priesthood, as it existed, became a very incorrect interpreter of
public opinion in religious questions. The belief in the gods of Olympus had
been shaken as early as the age of Pericles, and underwent many modifications
after the Macedonian conquests. From the time the Romans became masters of
Greece, the majority of the educated were votaries of the different
philosophical sects, —every one of which viewed the established religion as a
mere popular delusion. But the Roman government, and the municipal authorities,
continued to support the various religions of the different provinces in their
legal rights, though the priesthood generally enjoyed this support rather in
their character of constituted corporations than because they were regarded as
spiritual guides. The amount of their revenues, and the extent of their civic
rights and privileges, were the chief objects which engaged the attention of
the magistrate.
The wealth and number of the religious establishments in Greece, and the
large funds possessed by corporations, which were appropriated to public festivals,
contributed in no small degree to encourage idleness among the people, and
perpetuate a taste for extravagance. The great festivals of the Olympic,
Pythic, and Isthmian games, in so far as they served to unite the whole Greek
nation in a common place of assembly for national objects, were, indeed,
productive of many advantages. They contributed to maintain a general standard
of public opinion throughout the Hellenic race, and they kept up a feeling of
nationality. But the dissipation occasioned by the multitude of local religious
feasts and public amusements, produced the most injurious effects on society.
The privilege called the right of asylum, by which some ancient temples
became sanctuaries where fugitive slaves were protected against the vengeance
of their masters, where debtors could escape the pursuit of their creditors,
and where the worst criminals defied the justice of the law, tended to
encourage the open violation of every principle of justice. The fear of
punishment, the strength of moral obligations, and the respect due to religion,
were destroyed by the impunity thus openly granted to the most heinous crimes.
This abuse had extended to such a degree under the Roman government, that the
senate found it necessary, in the reign of Tiberius, to mitigate the evil; but
superstition was too powerful to allow a complete reform, and many shrines were
allowed to retain the right of asylum to a much later period.
Though ancient superstitions were still practised, old religious feelings
were extinct. The oracles, which had once formed the most remarkable of the
sacred institutions of the Greeks, had fallen into decay. It is, however,
incorrect to suppose that the Pythoness ceased to deliver her responses from
the time of our Saviour’s birth, for she was consulted by the emperors long
after. Many oracles continued to be in considerable repute, even after the
introduction of Christianity into Greece. Pausanias mentions the oracle of
Mallos, in Cilicia, as the most veracious in his time. Claros and Didymi were
famous, and much consulted in the time of Lucian; and even new oracles were
commenced as a profitable speculation. The oracles continued to give their
responses to fervent votaries, long after they had fallen into general neglect
Julian endeavoured to revive their influence, and he consulted those of Delphi,
Delos, and Dodona, concerning the result of his Persian expedition. He vainly
attempted to restore Delphi, and Daphne, near Antioch, to their ancient
splendour. Even so late as the reign of Theodosius the Great, those of Delphi,
Didymi, and Jupiter Ammon, were in existence, but from that period they became
utterly silent. The reverence which had formerly been paid to them was
transferred to astrologers, who were consulted by all ranks and on all occasions.
Tiberius, Otho, Hadrian, and Severus, are all mentioned as votaries of this
mode of searching into the secrets of futurity. Yet hidden divination, to which
astrology belonged, had been prohibited by the laws of the twelve tables, and
was condemned both by express law and by the spirit of the Roman state
religion. It was regarded, even by the Greeks, as an illicit and disgraceful
practice.
During the first century of the Christian era, the worship of Serapis made
great progress in every part of the Roman Empire. This worship inculcated the
existence of another world, and of a future judgment. The fact deserves notice,
as it indicates the annihilation of all reverence for the old system of
paganism, and marks a desire in the public mind to search after those truths
which the Christian dispensation soon after revealed. A moral rule of life with
a religious sanction was a want which society began to feel when Christianity
appeared to supply it.
The religion of the Greeks was so worthless as a guide in morals, that the
destruction of priestly influence by the speculations of the philosophers
produced no worse effect than completing a separation in the intellectual
education of the higher and lower classes, which other causes had already
produced. The systems of the priests and the philosophers were in direct
opposition to one another, and philosophical enquiry undoubtedly did more for
intellectual improvement than could have been effected by the authority of a
religion so utterly destitute of intellectual power, and so compliant in its
form, as that of Greece. The attention which the Greeks always paid to
philosophy and metaphysical speculation, is a curious feature in their mental
character, and owes its origin, in part, to the happy logical analogies of
their native language; but, in the days of Grecian independence, this was only
a distinctive characteristic of a small portion of the cultivated minds in the
nation. From that peculiar condition of society which resulted from the
existence of a number of small independent states, a larger portion of the
nation was occupied with the higher branches of political business than has
ever been the case in any other equally numerous body of mankind. Every city in
Greece held the rank of a capital, and possessed its own statesmen and lawyers.
The sense of this importance, and the weight of this responsibility, stimulated
the Greeks to the extraordinary exertions of intellect with which their history
is filled; for the strongest spur to exertion among men is the existence of a
duty imposed as a voluntary obligation.
The habits of social intercourse, and the simple manner of life, which
prevailed in the Greek republics, rendered the private conduct of every
distinguished citizen as well known, and as constantly a subject of scrutiny to
his fellow-citizens, as his public career. This powerful agency of public
opinion served to enforce a conventional morality which, though lax in its
ethics, was at least imperative in its demands. But when the international
system of the Hellenic states was destroyed, when an altered condition of
society had introduced greater privacy into the habits of social life, and put
a stop to public intercourse among the citizens of the same region, by giving a
marked prominence to the distinctions of rank and wealth, the private conduct
of those who were engaged in public life was, in a great degree, withdrawn from
the examination of the people; and the effect of public opinion was gradually
weakened, as the grounds on which it was formed became less personal and
characteristic.
Political circumstances began, about the same time, to weaken the efficacy
of public opinion in affairs of government and administration. The want of some
substitute, to replace its powerful influence on the everyday conduct of man,
was so imperiously felt that one was eagerly sought for. Religion had long
ceased to be a guide in morality; and men strove to find some feeling which
would replace the forgotten fear of the gods, and that public opinion which
could once inspire self-respect. It was hoped that philosophy could supply the
want; and it was cultivated not only by the studious and the learned, but by
the world at large, in the belief that the self-respect of the philosopher
would prove a sure guide to pure morality, and inspire a deep sense of justice.
The necessity of obtaining some permanent power over the moral conduct of
mankind was naturally suggested to the Greeks by the political injustice under
which they suffered; and the hope that philosophical studies would temper the
minds of their masters to equity, and awaken feelings of humanity in their
hearts, could not fail to exert considerable influence. When the Romans
themselves had fallen into a state of moral and political degradation, lower
even than that of the Greeks, it is not surprising that the educated classes
should have cultivated philosophy with great eagerness, and with nearly similar
views. The universal craving after justice and truth affords a key to the
profound respect with which teachers of philosophy were regarded. Their
authority and their character were so high that they mixed with all ranks, and
preserved their power, in spite of all the ridicule of the satirists. The
general purity of their lives, and the justice of their conduct, were acknowledged,
though a few may have been corrupted by court favour; and pretenders may often
have assumed a long beard and dirty garments, to act the ascetic or the jester
with greater effect in the houses of the wealthy Romans. The inadequacy of any
philosophical opinions to produce the results required of them was, at last,
apparent in the changes and modifications which the various sects were
constantly making in the tenets of their founders, and the vain attempts that
were undertaken to graft the paganism of the past on the modern systems of
philosophy. The great principle of truth, which all were eagerly searching
after, seemed to elude their grasp; yet these investigations were not without
great use in improving the intellectual and moral condition of the higher
orders, and rendering life tolerable, when the tyranny and anarchy of the
imperial government threatened the destruction of society. They prepared the
minds of men for listening candidly to a purer religion, and rendered many of
the votaries of philosophy ready converts to the doctrines of Christianity.
Philosophy lent a splendour to the Greek name; yet, with the exception of
Athens, learning and philosophy were but little cultivated in European Greece.
The poverty of the inhabitants, and the secluded position of the country,
permitted few to dedicate their time to literary pursuits; and after the time
of the Antonines, the wealthy cities of Asia, Syria, and Egypt, contained the
real representatives of the intellectual supremacy of the Hellenic race. The
Greeks of Europe, unnoticed by history, were carefully cherishing their
national institutions; while, in the eyes of foreigners the Greek character and
fame depended on the civilization of an expatriated population, already
declining in number, and hastening to extinction. The social institutions of
the Greeks have, therefore, been even more useful to them in a national point
of view than their literature.
Sect. XIII
The Social Condition of the Greeks affected by the want of Colonies of
Emigration
The want of foreign colonies, which admitted of a constant influx of new
emigrants, must have exercised a powerful influence in arresting the progress
of society in the Roman world. Rome never, like Phoenicia and Greece, permitted
numerous bands of her citizens to depart from poverty in their own country, in
order to better their fortunes and enjoy the benefits of self-government as
independent communities in other lands. Her oligarchical constitution regarded
the people as the property of the State. Roman civilization moved only in the
train of the armies of Rome, and its progress was arrested when the career of
conquest stopped. For several ages war operated as a stimulant to population at
Rome, as colonization has served in modem times. It increased the general
wealth by an influx of slave labour, and excited the active energies of the
people, by opening a career of advancement. But the gains derived from an evil
source cannot be productive of permanent good. Even before the policy of
Augustus had established universal peace, and reduced the Roman army into a
corps of gendarmerie or armed police for guarding the internal tranquillity of
the provinces, or watching the frontiers, a combination of inherent defects in
the constitution of the Roman state had begun to destroy the lower order of
Roman citizens. The people required a new field of action when the old career
of conquest was closed for ever, in order to engage their energies in active
pursuits, and prevent them from pining away in poverty and idleness. The want
of colonies of emigration, at this conjuncture, kept all the evil elements of
the population fermenting within the State. The want of some distant spot
connected with the past history of their race, but freed from the existing
social restrictions which weighed heavily on the industrious, the ambitious,
and the proud, was required by the Romans to relieve society and render
political reforms possible. Various attempts were made to counteract the
poverty and the want of occupation among the free labourers which was produced
at Rome by every long cessation of war. C. Gracchus introduced the annual
distributions of grain, which became one of the principal causes of the ruin of
the republic; and Augustus established his colonies of legionaries over Italy
in a manner that accelerated its depopulation.
Military colonies, colonial municipalities, and the practice adopted by the
Roman citizens of seeking their fortunes in Spain, Gaul, and Britain, were an
imperfect substitute for modern emigration, though they long tended to preserve
an impulse towards improvement in the western portion of the Roman Empire. The
policy of the emperors was directed to render society stationary; and it
escaped the observation of profound statesmen, like Augustus and Tiberius, that
the most efficient means of securing it from decline consisted in the formation
of a regular demand on the population, by means of emigration. Foreign
colonization was, however, adverse to all the prejudices of a Roman. The policy
and religion of the State were equally opposed to the residence of any citizen
beyond the bounds of the empire; and the constant diminution of the inhabitants
of Italy, which accompanied the extended conquests of the republic, seemed to
indicate that the first duty of the masters of Italy was to encourage an influx
of population.
The decline in the population of Italy proceeded from evils inherent in the
political system of the Roman government. They exercised their influence in the
Grecian provinces of the empire, but they can only be traced with historical
accuracy, in their details, close to the centre of the executive power. The
system of administration in the republic had always tended to aggrandize the
aristocracy, who talked much of glory, but thought constantly of wealth. When
the conquests of Rome were extended over all the richest countries of the
ancient world, the leading families accumulated incredible riches, — riches,
indeed, far exceeding the wealth of modern sovereigns. Villas and parks were
formed over all Italy on a scale of the most sumptuous grandeur, and land
became more valuable as hunting-grounds than as productive farms. The same
habits were introduced into the provinces. In the neighbourhood of Rome,
agriculture was ruined by the public distributions of grain which was received
as tribute from the provinces, and by the bounty granted to importing merchants
in order to secure a low maximum price of bread. The public distributions at
Alexandria and Antioch must have proved equally injurious. Another cause of the
decline in the population of the empire was the great increase of the slaves
which took place on the rapid conquests of the Romans, and the diffusion of the
immense treasures suddenly acquired by their victories. There is always a
considerable waste of productive industry among a slave population; and free
labourers cease to exist, rather than perpetuate their race, if their labour be
degraded to the same level in society as that of slaves. When the insecurity of
property and person under the Roman government after the reign of Marcus
Aurelius, and the corrupt state of society, are added to these various causes
of decay, the decline and depopulation of the empire does not require farther
explanation.
Yet society would not, probably, have declined as it did, under the weight
of the Roman power, had the active, intelligent, and virtuous members of the
middle classes possessed the means of escaping from a social position so
calculated to excite feelings of despair. It is in vain to offer conjectures on
the subject; for the vice in the Roman constitution which rendered all their
military and state colonies merely sources of aggrandizement to the
aristocracy, may have proceeded from some inherent defect in the social
organization of the people, and, consequently, might have entailed ruin on any
Roman society established beyond the authority of the senate or the emperors.
The social organization of nations affects their vitality as much as their
political constitution affects their power and fortunes.
The exclusively Roman feeling, which was adverse to all foreign
colonization, was first attacked when Christianity spread itself beyond the
limits of the empire. The fact that Christianity was not identical with
citizenship, or, at least, with subjection to Rome, was a powerful cause of
creating that adverse feeling towards the Christians which branded them as
enemies of the human race; for, in the mouth of a Roman, the human race was a
phrase for the empire of Rome, and the Christians were really persecuted by
emperors like Trajan and Marcus Aurelius, because they were regarded as having
no attachment to the Roman government, because their humanity was stronger than
their citizenship.
Sect. XIV
Effects produced in Greece by the Inroads of the Goths
After the reign of Alexander Severus, the whole attention of the Roman
government was absorbed by the necessity of defending the empire against the
invasions of the northern nations. Two centuries of communication with the
Roman world had extended the effects of incipient civilization throughout all
the north of Europe. Trade had created new wants, and given a new impulse to
society. This state of improvement always causes a rapid increase of
population, and awakens a spirit of enterprise, which makes the apparent
increase even greater than the real. The history of every people which has
attained any eminence in the annals of mankind, has been marked by a similar
period of activity. The Greeks, the Romans, and the Arabs, poured out a
succession of armies, which must have astonished the nations which they
attacked, quite as much as the apparently inexhaustible armies of the Goths
amazed the degenerate Romans. Yet few events, in the whole course of history,
seem more extraordinary than the success of the uncivilized Goths against the
well-disciplined legions of imperial Rome, and their successful inroads into
the thickly-peopled provinces of the Roman Empire. The causes of this success
are evidently to be sought within the empire: the defenceless state of the
population, which was everywhere carefully disarmed, the oppression of the
provincials, the disorder in the finances, and the relaxation in the discipline
of the troops, contributed more to the victories of the Goths than their own
strength or military skill. If any national feeling, or common political
interest, had connected the people, the army, and the sovereign, the Roman
empire would have easily repulsed the attacks of all its enemies; nay, had the
government not placed itself in direct opposition to the interests of its
subjects, and arrested their natural progress by vicious legislation and
corrupt administration, the barbarous inhabitants of Germany, Poland, and
Russia, could have offered no more effective resistance to the advance of Roman
colonization than those of Spain, Gaul, and Britain. But the task of extending
the domain of civilization required to be supported by the energy of national
feelings; it was far beyond the strength of the imperial or any other central
government. The ablest of the despots who styled themselves the world’s
masters, did not dare, though nourished in camps, to attempt a career of
foreign conquest; these imperial soldiers were satisfied with the inglorious
task of preserving the limits of the empire without diminution. Even Severus,
after he had consolidated a systematic despotism, based on military power, did
not succeed in extending the empire. This avowed inability of the Roman armies
to make any further progress, invited the barbarians to attack the provinces.
If a body of assailants proved successful in breaking through the Roman lines,
they were sure of considerable plunder. If they were repulsed, they could
generally evade pursuit. These incursions were at first the enterprises of
armed bands and small tribes, but they became afterwards the employment of
armies and nations. To the timid eye of the unwarlike and unarmed citizens of
the empire, the whole population of the north appeared to be constantly on its
march, to plunder and enslave the wealthy and peaceable inhabitants of the
south.
Various means of defence were employed by the reigning sovereigns.
Alexander Severus secured the tranquillity of the frontiers by paying subsidies
to the barbarians: Decius fell, defending the provinces against an immense army
of Goths which had penetrated into the heart of Moesia; and Trebonianus Gallus
purchased the retreat of the victors by engaging to pay them an annual tribute.
The disorder in the Roman government increased, the succession of emperors
became more rapid, and the numbers of the invaders augmented. Various tribes
and nations, called, by the Greeks and Romans, Scythians and Goths, and
belonging to the great families of the Sclavonic and Germanic stock, under the
names of East and West Goths, Vandals, Heruls, Borans, Karps, Peuks, and
Urugunds, crossed the Danube. Their incursions were pushed through Moesia into
Thrace and Macedonia; an immense booty was carried away, and a still greater
amount of property was destroyed; thousands of the industrious inhabitants were
reduced to slavery, and a far greater number massacred by the cruelty of the
invaders.
The Greeks were awakened by these invasions from the state of lethargy in
which they had reposed for three centuries. They began to repair the long
neglected fortifications of their towns, and muster their city guards and rural
police, for a conflict in defence of their property. Cowardice had long been
supposed, by the Romans, to be an incurable vice of the Greeks, who had been
compelled to appear before the Romans with an obsequious and humble mien, and
every worthless Roman had thence arrogated to himself a fancied superiority.
But the truth is, that all the middle classes in the Roman world had, from the
time of Augustus, become averse to sacrificing their ease for the doubtful
glory to be gained in the imperial service. No patriotic feeling drew men to
the camp; and the allurements of ambition were stifled by obscurity of station
and hopelessness of promotion. The young nobility of Rome, when called upon to
serve in the legions, after the defeat of Varus, displayed signs of cowardice
unparalleled in the history of Greece. Like the Fellahs of modern Egypt, they
cut off their thumbs in order to escape military serviced Greece could
contribute but little to the defence of the empire; but Caracalla had drawn
from Sparta some recruits whom he formed into a Lacedaemonian phalanx. Decius,
before his defeat, intrusted the defence of Thermopylae to Claudius, who was
afterwards emperor, but who had only fifteen hundred regular troops, in
addition to the ordinary Greek militia of the cities. The smallness of the
number is curious; it indicates the tranquil condition of the Hellenic
population before the northern nations penetrated into the heart of the empire.
The preparations for defending the country were actively carried on, both
in northern Greece and at the Isthmus of Corinth. In the reign of Valerian the
walls of Athens, which had not been put in a proper state of defence from the
time of Sulla, were repaired, and the fortifications across the isthmus were
restored and garrisoned by Peloponnesian troops. It was not long before the
Greeks were called upon to prove the efficiency of their warlike arrangements.
A body of Goths, having established themselves along the northern shores of the
Black Sea, commenced a series of naval expeditions. They soon penetrated
through the Thracian Bosphorus, and, aided by additional bands who had
proceeded from the banks of the Danube by land, they marched into Asia Minor,
and plundered Chalcedon, Nicomedia, Nicaea, and Prusa, A.D. 259. This
successful enterprise was soon followed by still more daring expeditions.
In the year 267, another fleet, consisting of five hundred vessels, manned
chiefly by the Goths and Heruls, passed the Bosphorus and the Hellespont They
seized Byzantium and Chrysopolis, and advanced, plundering the islands and
coasts of the Aegean Sea, and laying waste many of the principal cities of the
Peloponnesus. Cyzicus, Lemnos, Skyros, Corinth, Sparta, and Argos, are named as
having suffered by their ravages. From the time of Sulla's conquest of Athens,
a period of nearly three hundred and fifty years had elapsed, during which
Attica had escaped the evils of war; yet when the Athenians were called upon to
defend their homes, they displayed a spirit worthy of their ancient fame. An
officer, named Cleodemus, had been sent by the government from Byzantium to
Athens, in order to repair the fortifications, but a division of these Goths
landed at the Piraeus, and succeeded in carrying Athens by storm, before any
means were taken for its defence. Dexippus, an Athenian of rank in the Roman
service, soon contrived to reassemble the garrison of the Acropolis; and by
joining to it such of the citizens as possessed some knowledge of military
discipline, or some spirit for warlike enterprise, he formed a little army of
two thousand men. Choosing a strong position in the Olive Grove, he
circumscribed the movements of the Goths, and so harassed them by a close
blockade that they were compelled to abandon Athens. Cleodemus, who was not at
Athens when it was surprised, had in the meantime assembled a fleet and gained
a naval victory over a division of the barbarian fleet. These reverses were a
prelude to the ruin of the Goths. A Roman fleet entered the Archipelago, and a
Roman army, under the emperor Gallienus, marched into Illyricum; the separate
divisions of the Gothic expedition were everywhere overtaken by these forces,
and destroyed in detail. During this invasion of the empire, one of the
divisions of the Gothic army crossed the Hellespont into Asia, and succeeded in
plundering the cities of the Troad, and in destroying the celebrated temple of
Diana of Ephesus.
Dexippus was himself the historian of the Gothic invasion of Attica, but,
unfortunately, little information on the subject can be collected from the
fragments of his works which now exist. There is a celebrated anecdote
connected with this incursion which throws some light on the state of the
Athenian population, and on the conduct of the Gothic invaders of the empire.
The fact of its currency is a proof of the easy circumstances in which the
Athenians lived, of the literary idleness in which they indulged, and the
general mildness of the assailants, whose sole object was plunder. It is said
that the Goths, when they had captured Athens, were preparing to burn the
splendid libraries which adorned the city; but that a Gothic soldier dissuaded
them, by telling his countrymen that it was better that the Athenians should
continue to waste their time in their halls and porticos over their books, than
that they should begin to occupy themselves with warlike exercises. Gibbon,
indeed, thinks the anecdote may be suspected as the fanciful conceit of a
recent sophist; and he adds, that the sagacious counsellor reasoned like an
ignorant barbarian. But the national degradation of the Greeks has co-existed
with their pre-eminence in learning during many centuries, so that it appears
that this ignorant barbarian reasoned like an able politician. Even the Greeks,
who repeated the anecdote, seem to have thought that there was more sound sense
in the arguments of the Goth than the great historian is willing to admit.
Something more than mere reading and study is required to form the judgment.
The cultivation of learning does not always bring with it the development of
good sense. It does not always render men wiser, and it generally proves
injurious to their bodily activity. When literary pursuits, therefore, become
the exclusive object of national ambition, and distinction in the cultivation
of literature and abstract science is more esteemed than sagacity and prudence
in the everyday duties of life, effeminacy is undoubtedly more likely to
prevail, than when literature is used as an instrument for advancing practical
acquirements and embellishing active occupations. The rude Goths themselves
would probably have admired the poetry of Homer and of Pindar, though they
despised the metaphysical learning of the schools of Athens.
The celebrity of Athens, and the presence of the historian Dexippus, have
given to this incursion of the barbarians a prominent place in history; but
many expeditions are casually mentioned, which must have inflicted greater
losses on the Greeks, and spread devastation more widely over the country.
These inroads must have produced important changes in the condition of the
Greek population, and given a new impulse to society. The passions of men were
called into action, and the protection of their property often depended on
their own exertions. Public spirit was again awakened, and many cities of
Greece successfully defended their walls against the armies of barbarians who
broke into the empire in the reign of Claudius. Thessalonica and Cassandra were
attacked by land and sea. Thessaly and Greece were invaded; but the walls of
the towns were generally found in a state of repair, and the inhabitants ready
to defend them. The great victory obtained by the emperor Claudius II, at
Naissus, broke the power of the Goths: and a Roman fleet in the Archipelago
destroyed the remains of their naval forces. The extermination of these
invaders was completed by a great plague which ravaged the East for fifteen
years.
During the repeated invasions of the barbarians, an immense number of
slaves were either destroyed or carried away beyond the Danube. Great
facilities were likewise afforded for the escape of dissatisfied slaves. The
numbers of the slave population in Greece must, therefore, have undergone a
reduction, which could not prove otherwise than beneficial to those who
remained, and which must also have produced a very considerable change on the
condition of the poorer freemen, the value of whose labour must have been considerably
increased. The danger in which men of wealth lived, necessitated an alteration
in their mode of life; every one was compelled to think of defending his
person, as well as his property; new activity was infused into society; and
thus it seems that the losses caused by the ravages of the Goths, and the
mortality produced by the plague, caused a general improvement in the
circumstances of the inhabitants of Greece.
It must here be observed, that the first great inroads of the northern
nations, who succeeded in penetrating into the heart of the Roman empire, were
directed against the eastern provinces, and that Greece suffered severely by
the earliest invasions; yet the eastern portion of the empire alone succeeded
in driving back the barbarians, and preserving its population free from any
admixture of the Gothic race. This successful resistance was chiefly owing to
the national feelings and political organization of the Greek people. The
institutions which the Greeks retained prevented them from remaining utterly
helpless in the moment of danger; the magistrates possessed a legitimate
authority to take measures for any extraordinary crisis, and citizens of wealth
and talent could render their services useful, without any violent departure
from the usual forms of the local administration. The evil of anarchy was not,
in Greece, added to the misfortune of invasion. Fortunately for the Greeks, the
insignificancy of their military forces prevented the national feelings, which
these measures aroused, from giving umbrage either to the Roman emperors or to
their military officers in the provinces.
From the various accounts of the Gothic wars of this period which exist, it
is evident that the expeditions of the barbarians were, as yet, only undertaken
for the purpose of plundering the provinces. The invaders entertained no idea
of being able to establish themselves permanently within the bounds of the
empire. The celerity of their movements generally made their numbers appear
greater than they really were; while the inferiority of their arms and
discipline rendered them an unequal match for a much smaller body of the
heavy-armed Romans. When the invaders met with a steady and well-combined
resistance, they were defeated without much difficulty; but whenever a moment
of neglect presented itself, their attacks were repeated with undiminished
courage. The victorious reigns of Claudius II, Aurelian, and Probus, prove the
immense superiority of the Roman armies when properly commanded; but the
custom, which was constantly gaining ground, of recruiting the legions from
among the barbarians, reveals the deplorable state of depopulation and weakness
to which three centuries of despotism and bad administration had reduced the
empire. On the one hand, the government feared the spirit of its subjects, if
intrusted with arms, far more than it dreaded the ravages of the barbarians;
and on the other, it was unwilling to reduce the number of the citizens paying
taxes, by draughting too large a proportion of the industrious classes into the
army. The imperial fiscal system rendered it necessary to keep all the
provincial landed proprietors carefully disarmed, lest they should revolt, and
perhaps make an attempt to revive republican institutions; and the defence of
the empire seemed, to the Roman emperors, to demand the maintenance of a larger
army than the population of their own dominions, from which recruits were
drawn, could supply.
Sect. XV
Changes which preceded the Establishment of Constantinople as the Capital
of the Roman Empire
The Romans had long been sensible that their social vices threatened their
empire with ruin, though they never contemplated the possibility of their
cowardice delivering it up a prey to barbarous conquerors. Augustus made a vain
attempt to stem the torrent of corruption, by punishing immorality in the
higher orders. But a privileged class is generally sufficiently powerful to be
able to form its own social code of morality, and protect its own vices as long
as it can maintain its existence. The immorality of the Romans at last
undermined the political fabric of the empire. Two centuries and a half after
the failure of Augustus, the emperor Decius endeavoured with as little effect
to reform society. Neither of these sovereigns understood how to cure the
malady which was destroying the State. They attempted to improve society by
punishing individual nobles for general vices. They ought to have annihilated
the privileges which raised senators and nobles above the influence of law and
public opinion, and subjected them to nothing but the despotic power of the
emperor. St. Paul, however, informs us that the whole frame of society was so
utterly corrupted that even this measure would have proved ineffectual. The
people were as vicious as the senate; all ranks were suffering from a moral
gangrene, which no human art could heal. The dangerous abyss to which society
was hastening did not escape observation. The alarm gradually spread through
every class in the wide extent of the Roman world. A secret terror was felt by
the emperors, the senators, and even by the armies. Men’s minds were changed,
and a divine influence produced a reform of which man’s wisdom and strength had
proved incapable. From the death of Alexander Severus to the accession of
Diocletian, a great social alteration is visible in paganism; the aspect of the
human mind seemed to have undergone a complete metamorphosis. The spirit of
Christianity was floating in the atmosphere, and to its influence we must
attribute that moral change in the pagan world, during the latter half of the
third century, which tended to prolong the existence of the Western Roman
Empire.
Foreign invasions, the disorderly state of the army, the weight of the
taxes, and the irregular constitution of the imperial government, produced at
this time a general feeling that the army and the State required a new
organization, in order to adapt both to the exigencies of altered
circumstances, and save the empire from impending ruin. Aurelian, Probus,
Diocletian, and Constantine, appeared as reformers of the Roman Empire. The
history of their reforms belongs to the records of the Roman constitution, as
they were conceived with very little reference to the institutions of the
provinces; and only some portion of the modifications then made in the form of
the imperial administration will fall within the scope of this work. But though
the administrative reforms produced little change in the condition of the Greek
population, the Greeks themselves actively contributed to effect a mighty revolution
in the whole frame of social life, by the organization which they gave to the
church from the moment they began to embrace the Christian religion. It must
not be overlooked, that the Greeks organized a Christian church before
Christianity became the established religion of the empire.
Diocletian found that the Roman Empire had lost much of its internal
cohesion, and that it could no longer be conveniently governed from one
administrative centre. He attempted to remedy the increasing weakness of the
coercive principle, by creating four centres of executive authority, controlled
by a single imperial legislative emperor. But no human skill could long
preserve harmony between four executive despots. Constantine restored the unity
of the Roman Empire. His reign marks the period in which old Roman political
feelings lost their power, and the superstitious veneration for Rome herself
ceased. The liberty afforded for new political ideas by the new social
organization was not overlooked by the Greeks. The transference of the seat of
government to Byzantium weakened the Roman spirit in the public administration.
The Romans, indeed, from the establishment of the imperial government, had
ceased to form a homogeneous people, or to be connected by feelings of
attachment and interest to one common country; and as soon as the rights of
Roman citizenship had been conferred on the provincials, Rome became a mere
ideal country to the majority of Romans. The Roman citizens, however, in many
provinces, formed a civilized caste of society, dwelling among a number of
ruder natives and slaves; they were not melted into the mass of the population.
In the Grecian provinces, no such distinction prevailed. The Greeks, who had
taken on themselves the name and the position of Roman citizens, retained their
own language, manners, and institutions; and as soon as Constantinople was
founded and became the capital of the empire, a struggle arose whether it was
to become a Greek or a Latin city.
Constantine himself does not appear to have perceived this tendency of the
Greek population to acquire a predominant influence in the East by supplanting
the language and manners of Rome, and he modelled his new capital entirely
after Roman ideas and prejudices. Constantinople was, at its foundation, a
Roman city, and Latin was the language of the higher ranks of its inhabitants.
This fact must not be lost sight of; for it affords an explanation of the
opposition which is for ages apparent in the feelings, as well as the
interests, of the capital and of the Greek nation. Constantinople was a
creation of imperial favour; a regard to its own advantage rendered it
subservient to despotism, and, for a long period, impervious to any national
feeling. The inhabitants enjoyed exemptions from taxation, and received
distributions of grain and provisions, so that the misery of the empire, and
the desolation of the provinces, hardly affected them. Left at leisure to enjoy
the games of the circus, they were bribed by government to pay little attention
to the affairs of the empire. Such was the position of the people of
Constantinople at the time of its foundation, and such it continued for many
centuries.
CHAPTER II.From the Establishment of Constantinople as Capital of the Roman Empire to the Accession of Justinian, A. D. 330-527
|