CRISTO RAUL.ORG |
READING HALLTHE DOORS OF WISDOM |
A HISTORY OF CHINACHAPTER XIII.THE PERIOD OF ABSOLUTISM(C)The Manchu Dynasty (1644-1911)1
Installation of Manchus
The Manchus had gained the mastery over China owing
rather to China's internal situation than to their military superiority. How
was it that the dynasty could endure for so long, although the Manchus were not
numerous, although the first Manchu ruler (Fu Lin, known under the rule name
Shun-chih; 1644-1662) was a psychopathic youth, although there were princes of
the Ming dynasty ruling in South China, and although there were strong groups
of rebels all over the country? The Manchus were aliens; at that time the
national feeling of the Chinese had already been awakened; aliens were
despised. In addition to this, the Manchus demanded that as a sign of their
subjection the Chinese should wear pigtails and assume Manchurian clothing (law
of 1645). Such laws could not but offend national pride. Moreover, marriages
between Manchus and Chinese were prohibited, and a dual government was set up,
with Manchus always alongside Chinese in every office, the Manchus being of
course in the superior position. The Manchu soldiers were distributed in
military garrisons among the great cities, and were paid state pensions, which
had to be provided by taxation. They were the master race, and had no need to
work. Manchus did not have to attend the difficult state examinations which the
Chinese had to pass in order to gain an appointment. How was it that in spite
of all this the Manchus were able to establish themselves?
The conquering Manchu generals first went south from
eastern China, and in 1645 captured Nanking, where a Ming prince had ruled. The
region round Nanking was the economic centre of China. Soon the Manchus were in
the adjoining southern provinces, and thus they conquered the whole of the
territory of the landowning gentry, who after the events of the beginning of
the seventeenth century had no longer trusted the Ming rulers. The Ming prince
in Nanking was just as incapable, and surrounded by just as evil a clique, as
the Ming emperors of the past. The gentry were not inclined to defend him. A
considerable section of the gentry were reduced to utter despair; they had no
desire to support the Ming any longer; in their own interest they could not
support the rebel leaders; and they regarded the Manchus as just a particular
sort of "rebels". Interpreting the refusal of some Sung ministers to
serve the foreign Mongols as an act of loyalty, it was now regarded as shameful
to desert a dynasty when it came to an end and to serve the new ruler, even if
the new régime promised to be better. Many thousands of officials, scholars,
and great landowners committed suicide. Many books, often really moving and
tragic, are filled with the story of their lives. Some of them tried to form
insurgent bands with their peasants and went into the mountains, but they were
unable to maintain themselves there. The great bulk of the élite soon brought
themselves to collaborate with the conquerors when they were offered tolerable
conditions. In the end the Manchus did not interfere in the ownership of land
in central China.
At the time when in Europe Louis XIV was reigning, the
Thirty Years War was coming to an end, and Cromwell was carrying out his
reforms in England, the Manchus conquered the whole of China. Chang Hsien-chung
and Li Tzŭ-ch'êng were the first to fall; the pirate Coxinga lasted a
little longer and was even able to plunder Nanking in 1659, but in 1661 he had
to retire to Formosa. Wu San-kui, who meanwhile had conquered western China,
saw that the situation was becoming difficult for him. His task was to drive
out the last Ming pretenders for the Manchus. As he had already been opposed to
the Ming in 1644, and as the Ming no longer had any following among the gentry,
he could not suddenly work with them against the Manchus. He therefore handed
over to the Manchus the last Ming prince, whom the Burmese had delivered up to
him in 1661. Wu San-kui's only possible allies against the Manchus were the
gentry. But in the west, where he was in power, the gentry counted for nothing;
they had in any case been weaker in the west, and they had been decimated by
the insurrection of Chang Hsien-chung. Thus Wu San-kui was compelled to try to
push eastwards, in order to unite with the gentry of the Yangtze region against
the Manchus. The Manchus guessed Wu San-kui's plan, and in 1673, after every
effort at accommodation had failed, open war came. Wu San-kui made himself
emperor, and the Manchus marched against him. Meanwhile, the Chinese gentry of
the Yangtze region had come to terms with the Manchus, and they gave Wu San-kui
no help. He vegetated in the south-west, a region too poor to maintain an army
that could conquer all China, and too small to enable him to last indefinitely
as an independent power. He was able to hold his own until his death, although,
with the loss of the support of the gentry, he had had no prospect of final
success. Not until 1681 was his successor, his grandson Wu Shih-fan, defeated.
The end of the rule of Wu San-kui and his successor marked the end of the
national governments of China; the whole country was now under alien
domination, for the simple reason that all the opponents of the Manchus had
failed. Only the Manchus were accredited with the ability to bring order out of
the universal confusion, so that there was clearly no alternative but to put up
with the many insults and humiliations they inflicted—with the result that the
national feeling that had just been aroused died away, except where it was kept
alive in a few secret societies. There will be more to say about this, once the
works which were suppressed by the Manchus are published.
In the first phase of the Manchu conquest the gentry
had refused to support either the Ming princes or Wu San-kui, or any of the
rebels, or the Manchus themselves. A second phase began about twenty years
after the capture of Peking, when the Manchus won over the gentry by desisting
from any interference with the ownership of land, and by the use of Manchu
troops to clear away the "rebels" who were hostile to the gentry. A
reputable government was then set up in Peking, free from eunuchs and from all
the old cliques; in their place the government looked for Chinese scholars for
its administrative posts. Literati and scholars streamed into Peking,
especially members of the "Academies" that still existed in secret,
men who had been the chief sufferers from the conditions at the end of the Ming
epoch. The young emperor Sheng Tsu (1663-1722; K'ang-hsi is the name by which
his rule was known, not his name) was keenly interested in Chinese culture and
gave privileged treatment to the scholars of the gentry who came forward. A
rapid recovery quite clearly took place. The disturbances of the years that had
passed had got rid of the worst enemies of the people, the formidable rival
cliques and the individuals lusting for power; the gentry had become more
cautious in their behavior to the peasants; and bribery had been largely
stamped out. Finally, the empire had been greatly expanded. All these things
helped to stabilize the regime of the Manchus.
2
Decline in the eighteenth century
The improvement continued until the middle of the
eighteenth century. About the time of the French Revolution there began a
continuous decline, slow at first and then gathering speed. The European works
on China offer various reasons for this: the many foreign wars (to which we
shall refer later) of the emperor, known by the name of his ruling period,
Ch'ien-lung, his craze for building, and the irruption of the Europeans into
Chinese trade. In the eighteenth century the court surrounded itself with great
splendour, and countless palaces and other luxurious buildings were erected,
but it must be borne in mind that so great an empire as the China of that day
possessed very considerable financial strength, and could support this luxury.
The wars were certainly not inexpensive, as they took place along the Russian
frontier and entailed expenditure on the transport of reinforcements and
supplies; the wars against Turkestan and Tibet were carried on with relatively
small forces. This expenditure should not have been beyond the resources of an
ordered budget. Interestingly enough, the period between 1640 and 1840 belongs to
those periods for which almost no significant work in the field of internal
social and economic developments has been made; Western scholars have been too
much interested in the impact of Western economy and culture or in the military
events. Chinese scholars thus far have shown a prejudice against the Manchu
dynasty and were mainly interested in the study of anti-Manchu movements and
the downfall of the dynasty. On the other hand, the documentary material for
this period is extremely extensive, and many years of work are necessary to
reach any general conclusions even in one single field. The following remarks
should, therefore, be taken as very tentative and preliminary, and they are,
naturally, fragmentary.
The decline of the Manchu dynasty began at a time when
the European trade was still insignificant, and not as late as after 1842, when
China had had to submit to the foreign Capitulations. These cannot have been
the true cause of the decline. Above all, the decline was not so noticeable in
the state of the Exchequer as in a general impoverishment of China. The number
of really wealthy persons among the gentry diminished, but the middle class,
that is to say the people who had education but little or no money and
property, grew steadily in number.
One of the deeper reasons for the decline of the
Manchu dynasty seems to lie in the enormous increase in the population. Here
are a few Chinese statistics:
It may be objected that these figures are incorrect
and exaggerated. Undoubtedly they contain errors. But the first figure (for
1578) of some sixty millions is in close agreement with all other figures of early
times; the figure for 1850 seems high, but cannot be far wrong, for even after
the great T'ai P'ing Rebellion of 1851, which, together with its after-effects,
costs the lives of countless millions, all statisticians of today estimate the
population of China at more than four hundred millions. If we enter these data
together with the census of 1953 into a chart, a fairly smooth curve emerges;
the special features are that already under the Ming the population was
increasing and, secondly, that the high rate of increase in the population
began with the long period of internal peace since about 1700. From that time
onwards, all China's wars were fought at so great a distance from China proper
that the population was not directly affected. Moreover, in the seventeenth and
eighteenth centuries the Manchus saw to the maintenance of the river dykes, so
that the worst inundations were prevented. Thus there were not so many of the
floods which had often cost the lives of many million people in China; and
there were no internal wars, with their heavy cost in lives.
But while the population increased, the tillage failed to increase in the needed proportion. I have, unfortunately, no statistics for all periods; but the general tendency is shown by the following table:
Six mou are about one acre. In 1578, there were 66 mou land per family of the total population. This was close to the figures regarded as ideal by Chinese early economists for the producing family (100 mou) considering the fact that about 80 per cent of all families at that time were producers. By 1729 it was only 35 mou per family, i.e. the land had to produce almost twice as much as before. We have shown that the agricultural developments in the Ming time greatly increased the productivity of the land. This then, obviously resulted in an increase of population. But by the middle of the eighteenth century, assuming that production doubled since the sixteenth century, population pressure was again as heavy as it had been then. And after c. 1750, population pressure continued to build up to the present time. Internal colonization continued during the Manchu
time; there was a continuous, but slow flow of people into Kwangsi, Kweichou,
Yünnan. In spite of laws which prohibited emigration, Chinese also moved into
South-East Asia. Chinese settlement in Manchuria was allowed only in the last
years of the Manchus. But such internal colonization or emigration could
allevitate the pressure only in some areas, while it continued to build up in
others.
In Europe as well as in Japan, we find a strong
population increase; in Europe at almost the same time as in China. But before
population pressure became too serious in Europe or Japan, industry developed
and absorbed the excess population. Thus, farms did not decrease too much in
size. Too small farms are always and in many ways uneconomical. With the
development of industries, the percentage of farm population decreased. In
China, however, the farm population was still as high as 73.3 per cent of the
total population in 1932 and the percentage rose to 81 per cent in 1950.
From the middle of the seventeenth century on,
commercial activities, especially along the coast, continued to increase and we
find gentry families who equip sons who were unwilling or not capable to study
and to enter the ranks of the officials, but who were too unruly to sit in
villages and collect the rent from the tenants of the family, with money to
enter business. The newly settled areas of Kwangtung and Kwangsi were ideal
places for them: here they could sell Chinese products to the native tribes or
to the new settlers at high prices. Some of these men introduced new techniques
from the old provinces of China into the "colonial" areas and set up
dye factories, textile factories, etc., in the new towns of the south. But the
greatest stimulus for these commercial activities was foreign, European trade.
American silver which had flooded Europe in the sixteenth century, began to
flow into China from the beginning of the seventeenth century on. The influx
was stopped not until between 1661 and 1684 when the government again
prohibited coastal shipping and removed coastal settlements into the interior
in order to stop piracy along the coasts of Fukien and independence movements
on Formosa. But even during these twenty-three years, the price of silver was
so low that home production was given up because it did not pay off. In the
eighteenth century, silver again continued to enter China, while silk and tea
were exported. This demand led to a strong rise in the prices of silk and tea,
and benefited the merchants. When, from the late eighteenth century on, opium
began to be imported, the silver left China again. The merchants profited this
time from the opium trade, but farmers had to suffer: the price of silver went
up, and taxes had to be paid in silver, while farm products were sold for
copper. By 1835, the ounce of silver had a value of 2,000 copper coins instead
of one thousand before 1800. High gains in commerce prevented investment in industries,
because they would give lower and later profits than commerce. From the
nineteenth century on, more and more industrial goods were offered by importers
which also prevented industrialization. Finally, the gentry basically remained
anti-industrial and anti-business. They tried to operate necessary enterprises
such as mining, melting, porcelain production as far as possible as government
establishments; but as the operators were officials, they were not too
business-minded and these enterprises did not develop well. The businessmen
certainly had enough capital, but they invested it in land instead of investing
it in industries which could at any moment be taken away by the government,
controlled by the officials or forced to sell at set prices, and which were
always subject to exploitation by dishonest officials. A businessman felt
secure only when he had invested in land, when he had received an official
title upon the payment of large sums of money, or when he succeeded to push at
least one of his sons into the government bureaucracy. No doubt, in spite of
all this, Chinese business and industry kept on developing in the Manchu time,
but they did not develop at such a speed as to transform the country from an
agrarian into a modern industrial nation.
3
Expansion in Central Asia; the first State treaty
The rise of the Manchu dynasty actually began under
the K'ang-hsi rule (1663-1722). The emperor had three tasks. The first was the
removal of the last supporters of the Ming dynasty and of the generals, such as
Wu San-kui, who had tried to make themselves independent. This necessitated a
long series of campaigns, most of them in the south-west or south of China;
these scarcely affected the population of China proper. In 1683 Formosa was
occupied and the last of the insurgent army commanders was defeated. It was
shown above that the situation of all these leaders became hopeless as soon as
the Manchus had occupied the rich Yangtze region and the intelligentsia and the
gentry of that region had gone over to them.
A quite different type of insurgent commander was the
Mongol prince Galdan. He, too, planned to make himself independent of Manchu
overlordship. At first the Mongols had readily supported the Manchus, when the
latter were making raids into China and there was plenty of booty. Now,
however, the Manchus, under the influence of the Chinese gentry whom they
brought, and could not but bring, to their court, were rapidly becoming Chinese
in respect to culture. Even in the time of K'ang-hsi the Manchus began to
forget Manchurian; they brought tutors to court to teach the young Manchus
Chinese. Later even the emperors did not understand Manchurian! As a result of
this process, the Mongols became alienated from the Manchurians, and the
situation began once more to be the same as at the time of the Ming rulers.
Thus Galdan tried to found an independent Mongol realm, free from Chinese
influence.
The Manchus could not permit this, as such a realm would
have threatened the flank of their homeland, Manchuria, and would have
attracted those Manchus who objected to sinification. Between 1690 and 1696
there were battles, in which the emperor actually took part in person. Galdan
was defeated. In 1715, however, there were new disturbances, this time in
western Mongolia. Tsewang Rabdan, whom the Chinese had made khan of the Ölöt,
rose against the Chinese. The wars that followed, extending far into Turkestan
and also involving its Turkish population together with the Dzungars, ended
with the Chinese conquest of the whole of Mongolia and of parts of eastern
Turkestan. As Tsewang Rabdan had tried to extend his power as far as Tibet, a
campaign was undertaken also into Tibet, Lhasa was occupied, a new Dalai Lama
was installed there as supreme ruler, and Tibet was made into a protectorate.
Since then Tibet has remained to this day under some form of Chinese colonial
rule.
This penetration of the Chinese into Turkestan took
place just at the time when the Russians were enormously expanding their empire
in Asia, and this formed the third problem for the Manchus. In 1650 the
Russians had established a fort by the river Amur. The Manchus regarded the
Amur (which they called the "River of the Black Dragon") as part of
their own territory, and in 1685 they destroyed the Russian settlement. After
this there were negotiations, which culminated in 1689 in the Treaty of
Nerchinsk. This treaty was the first concluded by the Chinese state with a
European power. Jesuit missionaries played a part in the negotiations as
interpreters. Owing to the difficulties of translation the text of the treaty,
in Chinese, Russian, and Manchurian, contained some obscurities, particulary in
regard to the frontier line. Accordingly, in 1727 the Russians asked for a
revision of the old treaty. The Chinese emperor, whose rule name was
Yung-cheng, arranged for the negotiations to be carried on at the frontier, in
the town of Kyakhta, in Mongolia, where after long discussions a new treaty was
concluded. Under this treaty the Russians received permission to set up a
legation and a commercial agency in Peking, and also to maintain a church. This
was the beginning of the foreign Capitulations. From the Chinese point of view
there was nothing special in a facility of this sort. For some fifteen
centuries all the "barbarians" who had to bring tribute had been
given houses in the capital, where their envoys could wait until the emperor
would receive them—usually on New Year's Day. The custom had sprung up at the
reception of the Huns. Moreover, permission had always been given for envoys to
be accompanied by a few merchants, who during the envoy's stay did a certain
amount of business. Furthermore the time had been when the Uighurs were
permitted to set up a temple of their own. At the time of the permission given
to the Russians to set up a "legation", a similar office was set up
(in 1729) for "Uighur" peoples (meaning Mohammedans), again under the
control of an office, called the Office for Regulation of Barbarians. The
Mohammedan office was placed under two Mohammedan leaders who lived in Peking.
The Europeans, however, had quite different ideas about a "legation",
and about the significance of permission to trade. They regarded this as the
opening of diplomatic relations between states on terms of equality, and the
carrying on of trade as a special privilege, a sort of Capitulation. This
reciprocal misunderstanding produced in the nineteenth century a number of
serious political conflicts. The Europeans charged the Chinese with breach of
treaties, failure to meet their obligations, and other such things, while the
Chinese considered that they had acted with perfect correctness.
4
Culture
In this K'ang-hsi period culture began to flourish
again. The emperor had attracted the gentry, and so the intelligentsia, to his
court because his uneducated Manchus could not alone have administered the
enormous empire; and he showed great interest in Chinese culture, himself
delved deeply into it, and had many works compiled, especially works of an
encyclopaedic character. The encyclopaedias enabled information to be rapidly
gained on all sorts of subjects, and thus were just what an interested ruler
needed, especially when, as a foreigner, he was not in a position to gain
really thorough instruction in things Chinese. The Chinese encyclopaedias of
the seventeenth and especially of the eighteenth century were thus the outcome
of the initiative of the Manchurian emperor, and were compiled for his
information; they were not due, like the French encyclopaedias of the
eighteenth century, to a movement for the spread of knowledge among the people.
For this latter purpose the gigantic encyclopaedias of the Manchus, each of
which fills several bookcases, were much too expensive and were printed in much
too limited editions. The compilations began with the great geographical
encyclopaedia of Ku Yen-wu (1613-1682), and attained their climax in the
gigantic eighteenth-century encyclopaedia T'u-shu chi-ch'eng, scientifically impeccable
in the accuracy of its references to sources. Here were already the beginnings
of the "Archaeological School", built up in the course of the
eighteenth century. This school was usually called "Han school"
because the adherents went back to the commentaries of the classical texts
written in Han time and discarded the orthodox explanations of Chu Hsi's school
of Sung time. Later, its most prominent leader was Tai Chen (1723-1777). Tai
was greatly interested in technology and science; he can be regarded as the
first philosopher who exhibited an empirical, scientific way of thinking. Late
nineteenth and early twentieth century Chinese scholarship is greatly obliged
to him.
The most famous literary works of the Manchu epoch
belong once more to the field which Chinese do not regard as that of true
literature—the novel, the short story, and the drama. Poetry did exist,
but it kept to the old paths and had few fresh ideas. All the various forms of
the Sung period were made use of. The essayists, too, offered nothing new,
though their number was legion. One of the best known is Yüan Mei (1716-1797),
who was also the author of the collection of short stories Tse-pu-yü ("The
Master did not tell"), which is regarded very highly by the Chinese. The
volume of short stories entitled Liao-chai chich-i, by P'u Sung-lin
(1640-1715?), is world-famous and has been translated into every civilized
language. Both collections are distinguished by their simple but elegant style.
The short story was popular among the greater gentry; it abandoned the popular
style it had had in the Ming epoch, and adopted the polished language of
scholars.
The Manchu epoch has left to us what is by general
consent the finest novel in Chinese literature, Hung-lou-meng ("The Dream
of the Red Chamber"), by Ts'ao Hsüeh-ch'in, who died in 1763. It describes
the downfall of a rich and powerful family from the highest rank of the gentry,
and the decadent son's love of a young and emotional lady of the highest
circles. The story is clothed in a mystical garb that does something to soften
its tragic ending. The interesting novel Ju-lin wai-shih ("Private Reports
from the Life of Scholars"), by Wu Ching-tzŭ (1701-1754), is a
mordant criticism of Confucianism with its rigid formalism, of the social
system, and of the examination system. Social criticism is the theme of many
novels. The most modern in spirit of the works of this period is perhaps the
treatment of feminism in the novel Ching-hua-yüan, by Li Yu-chên (d. 1830),
which demanded equal rights for men and women.
The drama developed quickly in the Manchu epoch,
particularly in quantity, especially since the emperors greatly appreciated the
theatre. A catalogue of plays compiled in 1781 contains 1,013 titles! Some of
these dramas were of unprecedented length. One of them was played in 26 parts
containing 240 acts; a performance took two years to complete! Probably the
finest dramas of the Manchu epoch are those of Li Yü (born 1611), who also
became the first of the Chinese dramatic critics. What he had to say about the
art of the theatre, and about aesthetics in general, is still worth reading.
About the middle of the nineteenth century the
influence of Europe became more and more marked. Translation began with Yen Fu
(1853-1921), who translated the first philosophical and scientific books and
books on social questions and made his compatriots acquainted with Western
thought. At the same time Lin Shu (1852-1924) translated the first Western
short stories and novels. With these two began the new style, which was soon
elaborated by Liang Ch'i-ch'ao, a collaborator of Sun Yat-sen's, and by others,
and which ultimately produced the "literary revolution" of 1917.
Translation has continued to this day; almost every book of outstanding importance
in world literature is translated within a few months of its appearance, and on
the average these translations are of a fairly high level.
Particularly fine work was produced in the field of
porcelain in the Manchu epoch. In 1680 the famous kilns in the province of
Kiangsi were reopened, and porcelain that is among the most artistically
perfect in the world was fired in them. Among the new colours were especially
green shades (one group is known as famille verte), and also black and yellow
compositions. Monochrome porcelain also developed further, including very fine
dark blue, brilliant red (called "ox-blood"), and white. In the
eighteenth century, however, there began an unmistakable decline, which has
continued to this day, although there are still a few craftsmen and a few kilns
that produce outstanding work (usually attempts to imitate old models), often
in small factories.
In painting, European influence soon shows itself. The
best-known example of this is Lang Shih-ning, an Italian missionary whose
original name was Giuseppe Castiglione (1688-1766); he began to work in China
in 1715. He learned the Chinese method of painting, but introduced a number of
technical tricks of European painters, which were adopted in general practice
in China, especially by the official court painters: the painting of the
scholars who lived in seclusion remained uninfluenced. Dutch flower-painting
also had some influence in China as early as the eighteenth century.
The missionaries played an important part at court.
The first Manchu emperors were as generous in this matter as the Mongols had
been, and allowed the foreigners to work in peace. They showed special interest
in the European science introduced by the missionaries; they had less sympathy
for their religious message. The missionaries, for their part, sent to Europe
enthusiastic accounts of the wonderful conditions in China, and so helped to
popularize the idea that was being formed in Europe of an
"enlightened", a constitutional, monarchy. The leaders of the
Enlightenment read these reports with enthusiasm, with the result that they had
an influence on the French Revolution. Confucius was found particularly
attractive, and was regarded as a forerunner of the Enlightenment. The
"Monadism" of the philosopher Leibniz was influenced by these
reports.
The missionaries gained a reputation at court as
"scientists", and in this they were of service both to China and to
Europe. The behaviour of the European merchants who followed the missions,
spreading gradually in growing numbers along the coasts of China, was not by
any means so irreproachable. The Chinese were certainly justified when they
declared that European ships often made landings on the coast and simply
looted, just as the Japanese had done before them. Reports of this came to the
court, and as captured foreigners described themselves as
"Christians" and also seemed to have some connection with the
missionaries living at court, and as disputes had broken out among the
missionaries themselves in connection with papal ecclesiastical policy, in the
Yung-cheng period (1723-1736; the name of the emperor was Shih Tsung)
Christianity was placed under a general ban, being regarded as a secret
political organization.
5
Relations with the outer world
During the Yung-cheng period there was long-continued
guerrilla fighting with natives in south-west China. The pressure of population
in China sought an outlet in emigration. More and more Chinese moved into the
south-west, and took the land from the natives, and the fighting was the
consequence of this.
At the beginning of the Ch'ien-lung period
(1736-1796), fighting started again in Turkestan. Mongols, now called Kalmuks,
defeated by the Chinese, had migrated to the Ili region, where after heavy
fighting they gained supremacy over some of the Kazaks and other Turkish
peoples living there and in western Turkestan. Some Kazak tribes went over to
the Russians, and in 1735 the Russian colonialists founded the town of Orenburg
in the western Kazak region. The Kalmuks fought the Chinese without cessation
until, in 1739, they entered into an agreement under which they ceded half
their territory to Manchu China, retaining only the Ili region. The Kalmuks
subsequently reunited with other sections of the Kazaks against the Chinese. In
1754 peace was again concluded with China, but it was followed by raids on both
sides, so that the Manchus determined to enter on a great campaign against the
Ili region. This ended with a decisive victory for the Chinese (1755). In the
years that followed, however, the Chinese began to be afraid that the various
Kazak tribes might unite in order to occupy the territory of the Kalmuks, which
was almost unpopulated owing to the mass slaughter of Kalmuks by the Chinese.
Unrest began among the Mohammedans throughout the neighbouring western
Turkestan, and the same Chinese generals who had fought the Kalmuks marched
into Turkestan and captured the Mohammedan city states of Uch, Kashgar, and
Yarkand.
The reinforcements for these campaigns, and for the
garrisons which in the following decades were stationed in the Ili region and
in the west of eastern Turkestan, marched along the road from Peking that leads
northward through Mongolia to the far distant Uliassutai and Kobdo. The cost of
transport for one shih (about 66 lb.) amounted to 120 pieces of silver. In 1781
certain economies were introduced, but between 1781 and 1791 over 30,000 tons,
making some 8 tons a day, was transported to that region. The cost of transport
for supplies alone amounted in the course of time to the not inconsiderable sum
of 120,000,000 pieces of silver. In addition to this there was the cost of the
transported goods and of the pay of soldiers and of the administration. These
figures apply to the period of occupation, of relative peace: during the actual
wars of conquest the expenditure was naturally far higher. Thus these
campaigns, though I do not think they brought actual economic ruin to China, were
nevertheless a costly enterprise, and one which produced little positive
advantage.
In addition to this, these wars brought China into
conflict with the European colonial powers. In the years during which the
Chinese armies were fighting in the Ili region, the Russians were putting out
their feelers in that direction, and the Chinese annals show plainly how the
Russians intervened in the fighting with the Kalmuks and Kazaks. The Ili region
remained thereafter a bone of contention between China and Russia, until it
finally went to Russia, bit by bit, between 1847 and 1881. The Kalmuks and
Kazaks played a special part in Russo-Chinese relations. The Chinese had sent a
mission to the Kalmuks farthest west, by the lower Volga, and had entered into
relations with them, as early as 1714. As Russian pressure on the Volga region
continually grew, these Kalmuks (mainly the Turgut tribe), who had lived there
since 1630, decided to return into Chinese territory (1771). During this
enormously difficult migration, almost entirely through hostile territory, a
large number of the Turgut perished; 85,000, however, reached the Ili region,
where they were settled by the Chinese on the lands of the eastern Kalmuks, who
had been largely exterminated.
In the south, too, the Chinese came into direct touch
with the European powers. In 1757 the English occupied Calcutta, and in 1766
the province of Bengal. In 1767 a Manchu general, Ming Jui, who had been
victorious in the fighting for eastern Turkestan, marched against Burma, which
was made a dependency once more in 1769. And in 1790-1791 the Chinese conquered
Nepal, south of Tibet, because Nepalese had made two attacks on Tibet. Thus
English and Chinese political interests came here into contact.
For the Ch'ien-lung period's many wars of conquest
there seem to have been two main reasons. The first was the need for security.
The Mongols had to be overthrown because otherwise the homeland of the Manchus
was menaced; in order to make sure of the suppression of the eastern Mongols,
the western Mongols (Kalmuks) had to be overthrown; to make them harmless,
Turkestan and the Ili region had to be conquered; Tibet was needed for the
security of Turkestan and Mongolia—and so on. Vast territories, however, were
conquered in this process which were of no economic value, and most of which
actually cost a great deal of money and brought nothing in. They were conquered
simply for security. That advantage had been gained: an aggressor would have to
cross great areas of unproductive territory, with difficult conditions for
reinforcements, before he could actually reach China. In the second place, the
Chinese may actually have noticed the efforts that were being made by the
European powers, especially Russia and England, to divide Asia among
themselves, and accordingly they made sure of their own good share.
6
Decline; revolts
The period of Ch'ien-lung is not only that of the
greatest expansion of the Chinese empire, but also that of the greatest
prosperity under the Manchu regime. But there began at the same time to be
signs of internal decline. If we are to fix a particular year for this, perhaps
it should be the year 1774, in which came the first great popular rising, in
the province of Shantung. In 1775 there came another popular rising, in
Honan—that of the "Society of the White Lotus". This society, which
had long existed as a secret organization and had played a part in the Ming
epoch, had been reorganized by a man named Liu Sung. Liu Sung was captured and
was condemned to penal servitude. His followers, however, regrouped themselves,
particularly in the province of Anhui. These risings had been produced, as
always, by excessive oppression of the people by the government or the
governing class. As, however, the anger of the population was naturally
directed also against the idle Manchus of the cities, who lived on their state
pensions, did no work, and behaved as a ruling class, the government saw in
these movements a nationalist spirit, and took drastic steps against them. The popular
leaders now altered their programme, and acclaimed a supposed descendant from
the Ming dynasty as the future emperor. Government troops caught the leader of
the "White Lotus" agitation, but he succeeded in escaping. In the
regions through which the society had spread, there then began a sort of
Inquisition, of exceptional ferocity. Six provinces were affected, and in and
around the single city of Wuch'ang in four months more than 20,000 people were
beheaded. The cost of the rising to the government ran into millions. In answer
to this oppression, the popular leaders tightened their organization and
marched north-west from the western provinces of which they had gained control.
The rising was suppressed only by a very big military operation, and not until
1802. There had been very heavy fighting between 1793 and 1802—just when in
Europe, in the French Revolution, another oppressed population won its freedom.
The Ch'ien-lung emperor abdicated on New Year's Day,
1795, after ruling for sixty years. He died in 1799. His successor was Jen
Tsung (1796-1821; reign name: Chia-ch'ing). In the course of his reign the
rising of the "White Lotus" was suppressed, but in 1813 there began a
new rising, this time in North China—again that of a secret organization, the
"Society of Heaven's Law". One of its leaders bribed some eunuchs,
and penetrated with a group of followers into the palace; he threw himself upon
the emperor, who was only saved through the intervention of his son. At the
same time the rising spread in the provinces. Once more the government
succeeded in suppressing it and capturing the leaders. But the memory of these
risings was kept alive among the Chinese people. For the government failed to
realize that the actual cause of the risings was the general impoverishment,
and saw in them a nationalist movement, thus actually arousing a national
consciousness, stronger than in the Ming epoch, among the middle and lower
classes of the people, together with hatred of the Manchus. They were held
responsible for every evil suffered, regardless of the fact that similar evils
had existed earlier.
7
European Imperialism in the Far East
With the Tao-kuang period (1821-1850) began a new
period in Chinese history, which came to an end only in 1911.
In foreign affairs these ninety years were marked by
the steadily growing influence of the Western powers, aimed at turning China
into a colony. Culturally this period was that of the gradual infiltration of
Western civilization into the Far East; it was recognized in China that it was
necessary to learn from the West. In home affairs we see the collapse of the
dynasty and the destruction of the unity of the empire; of four great civil
wars, one almost brought the dynasty to its end. North and South China, the
coastal area and the interior, developed in different ways.
Great Britain had made several attempts to improve her
trade relations with China, but the mission of 1793 had no success, and that of
1816 also failed. English merchants, like all foreign merchants, were only
permitted to settle in a small area adjoining Canton and at Macao, and were
only permitted to trade with a particular group of monopolists, known as the
"Hong". The Hong had to pay taxes to the state, but they had a wonderful
opportunity of enriching themselves. The Europeans were entirely at their
mercy, for they were not allowed to travel inland, and they were not allowed to
try to negotiate with other merchants, to secure lower prices by competition.
The Europeans concentrated especially on the purchase
of silk and tea; but what could they import into China? The higher the price of
the goods and the smaller the cargo space involved, the better were the chances
of profit for the merchants. It proved, however, that European woollens or
luxury goods could not be sold; the Chinese would probably have been glad to
buy food, but transport was too expensive to permit profitable business. Thus a
new article was soon discovered—opium, carried from India to China: the price
was high and the cargo space involved was very small. The Chinese were familiar
with opium, and bought it readily. Accordingly, from 1800 onwards opium became
more and more the chief article of trade, especially for the English, who were
able to bring it conveniently from India. Opium is harmful to the people; the
opium trade resulted in certain groups of merchants being inordinately
enriched; a great deal of Chinese money went abroad. The government became
apprehensive and sent Lin Tsê-hsü as its commissioner to Canton. In 1839 he
prohibited the opium trade and burned the chests of opium found in British
possession. The British view was that to tolerate the Chinese action might mean
the destruction of British trade in the Far East and that, on the other hand,
it might be possible by active intervention to compel the Chinese to open other
ports to European trade and to shake off the monopoly of the Canton merchants.
In 1840 British ships-of-war appeared off the south-eastern coast of China and
bombarded it. In 1841 the Chinese opened negotiations and dismissed Lin
Tsê-hsü. As the Chinese concessions were regarded as inadequate, hostilities
continued; the British entered the Yangtze estuary and threatened Nanking. In
this first armed conflict with the West, China found herself defenceless owing
to her lack of a navy, and it was also found that the European weapons were far
superior to those of the Chinese. In 1842 China was compelled to capitulate:
under the Treaty of Nanking Hong Kong was ceded to Great Britain, a war indemnity
was paid, certain ports were thrown open to European trade, and the monopoly
was brought to an end. A great deal of opium came, however, into China through
smuggling—regrettably, for the state lost the customs revenue!
This treaty introduced the period of the
Capitulations. It contained the dangerous clause which added most to China's
misfortunes—the Most Favoured Nation clause, providing that if China granted
any privilege to any other state, that privilege should also automatically be
granted to Great Britain. In connection with this treaty it was agreed that the
Chinese customs should be supervised by European consuls; and a trade treaty
was granted. Similar treaties followed in 1844 with France and the United
States. The missionaries returned; until 1860, however, they were only
permitted to work in the treaty ports. Shanghai was thrown open in 1843, and
developed with extraordinary rapidity from a town to a city of a million and a
centre of world-wide importance.
The terms of the Nanking Treaty were not observed by
either side; both evaded them. In order to facilitate the smuggling, the
British had permitted certain Chinese junks to fly the British flag. This also
enabled these vessels to be protected by British ships-of-war from pirates,
which at that time were very numerous off the southern coast owing to the
economic depression. The Chinese, for their part, placed every possible
obstacle in the way of the British. In 1856 the Chinese held up a ship sailing
under the British flag, pulled down its flag, and arrested the crew on
suspicion of smuggling. In connection with this and other events, Britain
decided to go to war. Thus began the "Lorcha War" of 1857, in which
France joined for the sake of the booty to be expected. Britain had just ended
the Crimean War, and was engaged in heavy fighting against the Moguls in India.
Consequently only a small force of a few thousand men could be landed in China;
Canton, however, was bombarded, and also the forts of Tientsin. There still
seemed no prospect of gaining the desired objectives by negotiation, and in
1860 a new expedition was fitted out, this time some 20,000 strong. The troops
landed at Tientsin and marched on Peking; the emperor fled to Jehol and did not
return; he died in 1861. The new Treaty of Tientsin (1860) provided for (a) the
opening of further ports to European traders; (b) the session of Kowloon, the
strip of land lying opposite Hong Kong; (c) the establishment of a British
legation in Peking; (d) freedom of navigation along the Yangtze; (e) permission
for British subjects to purchase land in China; (f) the British to be subject
to their own consular courts and not to the Chinese courts; (g) missionary
activity to be permitted throughout the country. In addition to this, the
commercial treaty was revised, the opium trade was permitted once more, and a
war indemnity was to be paid by China. In the eyes of Europe, Britain had now
succeeded in turning China not actually into a colony, but at all events into a
semi-colony; China must be expected soon to share the fate of India. China,
however, with her very different conceptions of intercourse between states, did
not realize the full import of these terms; some of them were regarded as
concessions on unimportant points, which there was no harm in granting to the
trading "barbarians", as had been done in the past; some were
regarded as simple injustices, which at a given moment could be swept away by
administrative action.
But the result of this European penetration was that
China's balance of trade was adverse, and became more and more so, as under the
commercial treaties she could neither stop the importation of European goods
nor set a duty on them; and on the other hand she could not compel foreigners
to buy Chinese goods. The efflux of silver brought general impoverishment to
China, widespread financial stringency to the state, and continuous financial
crises and inflation. China had never had much liquid capital, and she was soon
compelled to take up foreign loans in order to pay her debts. At that time
internal loans were out of the question (the first internal loan was floated in
1894): the population did not even know what a state loan meant; consequently
the loans had to be issued abroad. This, however, entailed the giving of
securities, generally in the form of economic privileges. Under the Most
Favoured Nation clause, however, these privileges had then to be granted to
other states which had made no loans to China. Clearly a vicious spiral, which
in the end could only bring disaster.
The only exception to the general impoverishment, in
which not only the peasants but the old upper classes were involved, was a
certain section of the trading community and the middle class, which had grown
rich through its dealings with the Europeans. These people now accumulated
capital, became Europeanized with their staffs, acquired land from the
impoverished gentry, and sent their sons abroad to foreign universities. They
founded the first industrial undertakings, and learned European capitalist methods.
This class was, of course, to be found mainly in the treaty ports in the south
and in their environs. The south, as far north as Shanghai, became more modern
and more advanced; the north made no advance. In the south, European ways of
thought were learnt, and Chinese and European theories were compared. Criticism
began. The first revolutionary societies were formed in this atmosphere in the
south.
8
Risings in Turkestan and within China: the T'ai P'ing
Rebellion
But the emperor Hsüan Tsung (reign name Tao-kuang), a
man in poor health though not without ability, had much graver anxieties than
those caused by the Europeans. He did not yet fully realize the seriousness of
the European peril.
In Turkestan, where Turkish Mohammedans lived under
Chinese rule, conditions were far from being as the Chinese desired. The
Chinese, a fundamentally rationalistic people, regarded religion as a purely
political matter, and accordingly required every citizen to take part in the
official form of worship. Subject to that, he might privately belong to any
other religion. To a Mohammedan, this was impossible and intolerable. The
Mohammedans were only ready to practise their own religion, and absolutely
refused to take part in any other. The Chinese also tried to apply to Turkestan
in other matters the same legislation that applied to all China, but this
proved irreconcilable with the demands made by Islam on its followers. All this
produced continual unrest.
Turkestan had had a feudal system of government with a
number of feudal lords (beg), who tried to maintain their influence and who had
the support of the Mohammedan population. The Chinese had come to Turkestan as
soldiers and officials, to administer the country. They regarded themselves as
the lords of the land and occupied themselves with the extraction of taxes.
Most of the officials were also associated with the Chinese merchants who
travelled throughout Turkestan and as far as Siberia. The conflicts implicit in
this situation produced great Mohammedan risings in the nineteenth century. The
first came in 1825-1827; in 1845 a second rising flamed up, and thirty years
later these revolts led to the temporary loss of the whole of Turkestan.
In 1848, native unrest began in the province of Hunan,
as a result of the constantly growing pressure of the Chinese settlers on the
native population; in the same year there was unrest farther south, in the
province of Kwangsi, this time in connection with the influence of the
Europeans. The leader was a quite simple man of Hakka blood, Hung Hsiu-ch'üan
(born 1814), who gathered impoverished Hakka peasants round him as every
peasant leader had done in the past. Very often the nucleus of these peasant
movements had been a secret society with a particular religious tinge; this
time the peasant revolutionaries came forward as at the same time the preachers
of a new religion of their own. Hung had heard of Christianity from
missionaries (1837), and he mixed up Christian ideas with those of ancient
China and proclaimed to his followers a doctrine that promised the Kingdom of
God on earth. He called himself "Christ's younger brother", and his
kingdom was to be called T'ai P'ing ("Supreme Peace"). He made his
first comrades, charcoal makers, local doctors, peddlers and farmers, into
kings, and made himself emperor. At bottom the movement, like all similar ones
before it, was not religious but social; and it produced a great response from
the peasants. The programme of the T'ai P'ing, in some points influenced by
Christian ideas but more so by traditional Chinese thought, was in many points
revolutionary: (a) all property was communal property; (b) land was classified
into categories according to its fertility and equally distributed among men
and women. Every producer kept of the produce as much as he and his family
needed and delivered the rest into the communal granary; (c) administration and
tax systems were revised; (d) women were given equal rights: they fought
together with men in the army and had access to official position. They had to
marry, but monogamy was requested; (e) the use of opium, tobacco and alcohol
was prohibited, prostitution was illegal; (f) foreigners were regarded as
equals, capitulations as the Manchus had accepted were not recognized. A large
part of the officials, and particularly of the soldiers sent against the
revolutionaries, were Manchus, and consequently the movement very soon became a
nationalist movement, much as the popular movement at the end of the Mongol
epoch had done. Hung made rapid progress; in 1852 he captured Hankow, and in
1853 Nanking, the important centre in the east. With clear political insight he
made Nanking his capital. In this he returned to the old traditions of the
beginning of the Ming epoch, no doubt expecting in this way to attract support
from the eastern Chinese gentry, who had no liking for a capital far away in
the north. He made a parade of adhesion to the ancient Chinese tradition: his
followers cut off their pigtails and allowed their hair to grow as in the past.
He did not succeed, however, in carrying his reforms
from the stage of sporadic action to a systematic reorganization of the
country, and he also failed to enlist the elements needed for this as for all
other administrative work, so that the good start soon degenerated into a
terrorist regime.
Hung's followers pressed on from Nanking, and in
1853-1855 they advanced nearly to Tientsin; but they failed to capture Peking
itself.
The new T'ai P'ing state faced the Europeans with big
problems. Should they work with it or against it? The T'ai P'ing always
insisted that they were Christians; the missionaries hoped now to have the
opportunity of converting all China to Christianity. The T'ai P'ing treated the
missionaries well but did not let them operate. After long hesitation and much
vacillation, however, the Europeans placed themselves on the side of the
Manchus. Not out of any belief that the T'ai P'ing movement was without
justification, but because they had concluded treaties with the Manchu government
and given loans to it, of which nothing would have remained if the Manchus had
fallen; because they preferred the weak Manchu government to a strong T'ai
P'ing government; and because they disliked the socialistic element in many of
the measured adopted by the Tai P'ing.
At first it seemed as if the Manchus would be able to
cope unaided with the T'ai P'ing, but the same thing happened as at the end of
the Mongol rule: the imperial armies, consisting of the "banners" of
the Manchus, the Mongols, and some Chinese, had lost their military skill in
the long years of peace; they had lost their old fighting spirit and were glad
to be able to live in peace on their state pensions. Now three men came to the
fore—a Mongol named Seng-ko-lin-ch'in, a man of great personal bravery, who
defended the interests of the Manchu rulers; and two Chinese, Tsêng Kuo-fan
(1811-1892) and Li Hung-chang (1823-1901), who were in the service of the
Manchus but used their position simply to further the interests of the gentry.
The Mongol saved Peking from capture by the T'ai P'ing. The two Chinese were
living in central China, and there they recruited, Li at his own expense and
Tsêng out of the resources at his disposal as a provincial governor, a sort of
militia, consisting of peasants out to protect their homes from destruction by
the peasants of the T'ai P'ing. Thus the peasants of central China, all
suffering from impoverishment, were divided into two groups, one following the
T'ai P'ing, the other following Tsêng Kuo-fan. Tsêng's army, too, might be
described as a "national" army, because Tsêng was not fighting for
the interests of the Manchus. Thus the peasants, all anti-Manchu, could choose
between two sides, between the T'ai P'ing and Tsêng Kuo-fan. Although Tsêng represented
the gentry and was thus against the simple common people, peasants fought in
masses on his side, for he paid better, and especially more regularly. Tsêng,
being a good strategist, won successes and gained adherents. Thus by 1856 the
T'ai P'ing were pressed back on Nanking and some of the towns round it; in 1864
Nanking was captured.
While in the central provinces the T'ai P'ing
rebellion was raging, China was suffering grave setbacks owing to the Lorcha
War of 1856; and there were also great and serious risings in other parts of
the country. In 1855 the Yellow River had changed its course, entering the sea
once more at Tientsin, to the great loss of the regions of Honan and Anhui. In
these two central provinces the peasant rising of the so-called "Nien Fei"
had begun, but it only became formidable after 1855, owing to the increasing
misery of the peasants. This purely peasant revolt was not suppressed by the
Manchu government until 1868, after many collisions. Then, however, there began
the so-called "Mohammedan risings". Here there are, in all, five
movements to distinguish: (1) the Mohammedan rising in Kansu (1864-5); (2) the
Salar movement in Shensi; (3) the Mohammedan revolt in Yünnan (1855-1873); (4)
the rising in Kansu (1895); (5) the rebellion of Yakub Beg in Turkestan (from
1866 onward).
While we are fairly well informed about the other
popular risings of this period, the Mohammedan revolts have not yet been well
studied. We know from unofficial accounts that these risings were suppressed
with great brutality. To this day there are many Mohammedans in, for instance,
Yünnan, but the revolt there is said to have cost a million lives. The figures
all rest on very rough estimates: in Kansu the population is said to have
fallen from fifteen millions to one million; the Turkestan revolt is said to
have cost ten million lives. There are no reliable statistics; but it is
understandable that at that time the population of China must have fallen
considerably, especially if we bear in mind the equally ferocious suppression
of the risings of the T'ai P'ing and the Nien Fei within China, and smaller
risings of which we have made no mention.
The Mohammedan risings were not elements of a general
Mohammedan revolt, but separate events only incidentally connected with each
other. The risings had different causes. An important factor was the general
distress in China. This was partly due to the fact that the officials were
exploiting the peasant population more ruthlessly than ever. In addition to
this, owing to the national feeling which had been aroused in so unfortunate a
way, the Chinese felt a revulsion against non-Chinese, such as the Salars, who
were of Turkish race. Here there were always possibilities of friction, which
might have been removed with a little consideration but which swelled to
importance through the tactless behaviour of Chinese officials. Finally there
came divisions among the Mohammedans of China which led to fighting between
themselves.
All these risings were marked by two characteristics.
They had no general political aim such as the founding of a great and universal
Islamic state. Separate states were founded, but they were too small to endure;
they would have needed the protection of great states. But they were not moved
by any pan-Islamic idea. Secondly, they all took place on Chinese soil, and all
the Mohammedans involved, except in the rising of the Salars, were Chinese.
These Chinese who became Mohammedans are called Dungans. The Dungans are, of
course, no longer pure Chinese, because Chinese who have gone over to Islam
readily form mixed marriages with Islamic non-Chinese, that is to say with
Turks and Mongols.
The revolt, however, of Yakub Beg in Turkestan had a
quite different character. Yakub Beg (his Chinese name was An Chi-yeh) had
risen to the Chinese governorship when he made himself ruler of Kashgar. In
1866 he began to try to make himself independent of Chinese control. He
conquered Ili, and then in a rapid campaign made himself master of all
Turkestan.
His state had a much better prospect of endurance than
the other Mohammedan states. He had full control of it from 1874. Turkestan was
connected with China only by the few routes that led between the desert and the
Tibetan mountains. The state was supported against China by Russia, which was
continually pressing eastward, and in the south by Great Britain, which was
pressing towards Tibet. Farther west was the great Ottoman empire; the attempt
to gain direct contact with it was not hopeless in itself, and this was recognized
at Istanbul. Missions went to and fro, and Turkish officers came to Yakub Beg
and organized his army; Yakub Beg recognized the Turkish sultan as Khalif. He
also concluded treaties with Russia and Great Britain. But in spite of all this
he was unable to maintain his hold of Turkestan. In 1877 the famous Chinese
general Tso Tsung-t'ang (1812-1885), who had fought against the T'ai P'ing and
also against the Mohammedans in Kansu, marched into Turkestan and ended Yakub
Beg's rule.
Yakub was defeated, however, not so much by Chinese
superiority as by a combination of circumstances. In order to build up his
kingdom he was compelled to impose heavy taxation, and this made him unpopular
with his own followers: they had had to pay taxes under the Chinese, but the
Chinese collection had been much less rigorous than that of Yakub Beg. It was
technically impossible for the Ottoman empire to give him any aid, even had its
internal situation permitted it. Britain and Russia would probably have been
glad to see a weakening of the Chinese hold over Turkestan, but they did not
want a strong new state there, once they had found that neither of them could
control the country while it was in Yakub Beg's hands. In 1881 Russia occupied
the Ili region, Yakub's first conquest. In the end the two great powers
considered it better for Turkestan to return officially into the hands of the
weakened China, hoping that in practice they would be able to bring Turkestan
more and more under their control. Consequently, when in 1880, three years
after the removal of Yakub Beg, China sent a mission to Russia with the request
for the return of the Ili region to her, Russia gave way, and the Treaty of Ili
was concluded, ending for the time the Russian penetration of Turkestan. In
1882 the Manchu government raised Turkestan to a "new frontier"
(Sinkiang) with a special administration.
This process of colonial penetration of Turkestan
continued. Until the end of the first world war there was no fundamental change
in the situation in the country, owing to the rivalry between Great Britain and
Russia. But after 1920 a period began in which Turkestan became almost
independent, under a number of rulers of parts of the country. Then, from 1928
onward, a more and more thorough penetration by Russia began, so that by 1940
Turkestan could almost be called a Soviet Republic. The second world war
diverted Russian attention to the West, and at the same time compelled the
Chinese to retreat into the interior from the Japanese, so that by 1943 the
country was more firmly held by the Chinese government than it had been for
seventy years. After the creation of the People's Democracy mass immigration
into Sinkiang began, in connection with the development of oil fields and of
many new industries in the border area between Sinkiang and China proper. Roads
and air communications opened Sinkiang. Yet, the differences between immigrant
Chinese and local, Muslim Turks, continue to play a role.
9
Collision with Japan; further Capitulations
The reign of Wen Tsung (reign name Hsien-feng
1851-1861) was marked throughout by the T'ai P'ing and other rebellions and by
wars with the Europeans, and that of Mu Tsung (reign name T'ung-chih:
1862-1874) by the great Mohammedan disturbances. There began also a conflict
with Japan which lasted until 1945. Mu Tsung came to the throne as a child of
five, and never played a part of his own. It had been the general rule for
princes to serve as regents for minors on the imperial throne, but this time the
princes concerned won such notoriety through their intrigues that the Peking
court circles decided to entrust the regency to two concubines of the late
emperor. One of these, called Tzŭ Hsi (born 1835), of the Manchu tribe of
the Yehe-Nara, quickly gained the upper hand. The empress Tzŭ Hsi was one
of the strongest personalities of the later nineteenth century who played an
active part in Chinese political life. She played a more active part than any
emperor had played for many decades.
Meanwhile great changes had taken place in Japan. The
restoration of the Meiji had ended the age of feudalism, at least on the
surface. Japan rapidly became Westernized, and at the same time entered on an
imperialist policy. Her aims from 1868 onward were clear, and remained
unaltered until the end of the second World War: she was to be surrounded by a
wide girdle of territories under Japanese domination, in order to prevent the
approach of any enemy to the Japanese homeland. This girdle was divided into several
zones—(1) the inner zone with the Kurile Islands, Sakhalin, Korea, the Ryukyu
archipelago, and Formosa; (2) the outer zone with the Marianne, Philippine, and
Caroline Islands, eastern China, Manchuria, and eastern Siberia; (3) the third
zone, not clearly defined, including especially the Netherlands Indies,
Indo-China, and the whole of China, a zone of undefined extent. The outward
form of this subjugated region was to be that of the Greater Japanese Empire,
described as the Imperium of the Yellow Race (the main ideas were contained in
the Tanaka Memorandum 1927 and in the Tada Interview of 1936). Round Japan,
moreover, a girdle was to be created of producers of raw materials and
purchasers of manufactures, to provide Japanese industry with a market. Japan
had sent a delegation of amity to China as early as 1869, and a first
Sino-Japanese treaty was signed in 1871; from then on, Japan began to carry out
her imperialistic plans. In 1874 she attacked the Ryukyu islands and Formosa on
the pretext that some Japanese had been murdered there. Under the treaty of
1874 Japan withdrew once more, only demanding a substantial indemnity; but in
1876, in violation of the treaty and without a declaration of war, she annexed
the Ryukyu Islands. In 1876 began the Japanese penetration into Korea; by 1885
she had reached the stage of a declaration that Korea was a joint sphere of
interest of China and Japan; until then China's protectorate over Korea had
been unchallenged. At the same time (1876) Great Britain had secured further
Capitulations in the Chefoo Convention; in 1862 France had acquired Cochin
China, in 1864 Cambodia, in 1874 Tongking, and in 1883 Annam. This led in 1884
to war between France and China, in which the French did not by any means gain
an indubitable victory; but the Treaty of Tientsin left them with their
acquisitions.
Meanwhile, at the beginning of 1875, the young Chinese
emperor died of smallpox, without issue. Under the influence of the two
empresses, who still remained regents, a cousin of the dead emperor, the
three-year-old prince Tsai T'ien was chosen as emperor Tê Tsung (reign name
Kuang-hsü: 1875-1909). He came of age in 1889 and took over the government of
the country. The empress Tzŭ Hsi retired, but did not really relinquish
the reins.
In 1894 the Sino-Japanese War broke out over Korea, as
an outcome of the undefined position that had existed since 1885 owing to the
imperialistic policy of the Japanese. China had created a North China squadron,
but this was all that can be regarded as Chinese preparation for the
long-expected war. The Governor General of Chihli (now Hopei—the province in
which Peking is situated), Li Hung-chang, was a general who had done good
service, but he lost the war, and at Shimonoseki (1895) he had to sign a treaty
on very harsh terms, in which China relinquished her protectorate over Korea
and lost Formosa. The intervention of France, Germany, and Russia compelled
Japan to content herself with these acquisitions, abandoning her demand for
South Manchuria.
10
Russia in Manchuria
After the Crimean War, Russia had turned her attention
once more to the East. There had been hostilities with China over eastern
Siberia, which were brought to an end in 1858 by the Treaty of Aigun, under
which China ceded certain territories in northern Manchuria. This made possible
the founding of Vladivostok in 1860. Russia received Sakhalin from Japan in
1875 in exchange for the Kurile Islands. She received from China the important
Port Arthur as a leased territory, and then tried to secure the whole of South
Manchuria. This brought Japan's policy of expansion into conflict with Russia's
plans in the Far East. Russia wanted Manchuria in order to be able to pursue a
policy in the Pacific; but Japan herself planned to march into Manchuria from
Korea, of which she already had possession. This imperialist rivalry made war
inevitable: Russia lost the war; under the Treaty of Portsmouth in 1905 Russia
gave Japan the main railway through Manchuria, with adjoining territory. Thus
Manchuria became Japan's sphere of influence and was lost to the Manchus
without their being consulted in any way. The Japanese penetration of Manchuria
then proceeded stage by stage, not without occasional setbacks, until she had
occupied the whole of Manchuria from 1932 to 1945. After the end of the second
world war, Manchuria was returned to China, with certain reservations in favour
of the Soviet Union, which were later revoked.
11
Reform and reaction: the Boxer Rising
China had lost the war with Japan because she was
entirely without modern armament. While Japan went to work at once with all her
energy to emulate Western industrialization, the ruling class in China had
shown a marked repugnance to any modernization; and the centre of this
conservatism was the dowager empress Tzŭ Hsi. She was a woman of strong
personality, but too uneducated—in the modern sense—to be able to realize that
modernization was an absolute necessity for China if it was to remain an
independent state. The empress failed to realize that the Europeans were
fundamentally different from the neighboring tribes or the pirates of the past;
she had not the capacity to acquire a general grasp of the realities of world
politics. She felt instinctively that Europeanization would wreck the
foundations of the power of the Manchus and the gentry, and would bring another
class, the middle class and the merchants, into power.
There were reasonable men, however, who had seen the
necessity of reform—especially Li Hung-chang, who has already been mentioned.
In 1896 he went on a mission to Moscow, and then toured Europe. The reformers
were, however, divided into two groups. One group advocated the acquisition of
a certain amount of technical knowledge from abroad and its introduction by
slow reforms, without altering the social structure of the state or the
composition of the government. The others held that the state needed
fundamental changes, and that superficial loans from Europe were not enough.
The failure in the war with Japan made the general desire for reform more and
more insistent not only in the country but in Peking. Until now Japan had been
despised as a barbarian state; now Japan had won! The Europeans had been
despised; now they were all cutting bits out of China for themselves, extracting
from the government one privilege after another, and quite openly dividing
China into "spheres of interest", obviously as the prelude to
annexation of the whole country.
In Europe at that time the question was being
discussed over and over again, why Japan had so quickly succeeded in making
herself a modern power, and why China was not succeeding in doing so; the
Japanese were praised for their capacity and the Chinese blamed for their
lassitude. Both in Europe and in Chinese circles it was overlooked that there
were fundamental differences in the social structures of the two countries. The
basis of the modern capitalist states of the West is the middle class. Japan
had for centuries had a middle class (the merchants) that had entered into a symbiosis
with the feudal lords. For the middle class the transition to modern
capitalism, and for the feudal lords the way to Western imperialism, was easy.
In China there was only a weak middle class, vegetating under the dominance of
the gentry; the middle class had still to gain the strength to liberate itself
before it could become the support for a capitalistic state. And the gentry
were still strong enough to maintain their dominance and so to prevent a
radical reconstruction; all they would agree to were a few reforms from which
they might hope to secure an increase of power for their own ends.
In 1895 and in 1898 a scholar, K'ang Yo-wei, who was
admitted into the presence of the emperor, submitted to him memoranda in which
he called for radical reform. K'ang was a scholar who belonged to the
empiricist school of philosophy of the early Manchu period, the so-called Han
school. He was a man of strong and persuasive personality, and had such an
influence on the emperor that in 1898 the emperor issued several edicts
ordering the fundamental reorganization of education, law, trade,
communications, and the army. These laws were not at all bad in themselves;
they would have paved the way for a liberalization of Chinese society. But they
aroused the utmost hatred in the conservative gentry and also in the moderate
reformers among the gentry. K'ang Yo-wei and his followers, to whom a number of
well-known modern scholars belonged, had strong support in South China. We have
already mentioned that owing to the increased penetration of European goods and
ideas, South China had become more progressive than the north; this had added
to the tension already existing for other reasons between north and south. In
foreign policy the north was more favourable to Russia and radically opposed to
Japan and Great Britain; the south was in favour of co-operation with Britain
and Japan, in order to learn from those two states how reform could be carried
through. In the north the men of the south were suspected of being anti-Manchu
and revolutionary in feeling. This was to some extent true, though K'ang Yo-wei
and his friends were as yet largely unconscious of it.
When the empress Tzŭ Hsi saw that the emperor was
actually thinking about reforms, she went to work with lightning speed. Very
soon the reformers had to flee; those who failed to make good their escape were
arrested and executed. The emperor was made a prisoner in a palace near Peking,
and remained a captive until his death; the empress resumed her regency on his
behalf. The period of reforms lasted only for a few months of 1898. A leading
part in the extermination of the reformers was played by troops from Kansu
under the command of a Mohammedan, Tung Fu-hsiang. General Yüan Shih-k'ai, who
was then stationed at Tientsin in command of 7,000 troops with modern
equipment, the only ones in China, could have removed the empress and protected
the reformers; but he was already pursuing a personal policy, and thought it
safer to give the reformers no help.
There now began, from 1898, a thoroughly reactionary
rule of the dowager empress. But China's general situation permitted no
breathing-space. In 1900 came the so-called Boxer Rising, a new popular
movement against the gentry and the Manchus similar to the many that had preceded
it. The Peking government succeeded, however, in negotiations that brought the
movement into the service of the government and directed it against the
foreigners. This removed the danger to the government and at the same time
helped it against the hated foreigners. But incidents resulted which the Peking
government had not anticipated. An international army was sent to China, and
marched from Tientsin against Peking, to liberate the besieged European
legations and to punish the government. The Europeans captured Peking (1900);
the dowager empress and her prisoner, the emperor, had to flee; some of the
palaces were looted. The peace treaty that followed exacted further concessions
from China to the Europeans and enormous war indemnities, the payment of which
continued into the 1940's, though most of the states placed the money at
China's disposal for educational purposes. When in 1902 the dowager empress
returned to Peking and put the emperor back into his palace-prison, she was
forced by what had happened to realize that at all events a certain measure of
reform was necessary. The reforms, however, which she decreed, mainly in 1904,
were very modest and were never fully carried out. They were only intended to
make an impression on the outer world and to appease the continually growing
body of supporters of the reform party, especially numerous in South China. The
south remained, nevertheless, a focus of hostility to the Manchus. After his
failure in 1898, K'ang Yo-wei went to Europe, and no longer played any
important political part. His place was soon taken by a young Chinese physician
who had been living abroad, Sun Yat-sen (1866-1925), who turned the reform
party into a middle-class revolutionary party.
12
End of the dynasty
Meanwhile the dowager empress held her own. General
Yüan Shih-k'ai, who had played so dubious a part in 1898, was not impeccably
loyal to her, and remained unreliable. He was beyond challenge the strongest
man in the country, for he possessed the only modern army; but he was still
biding his time.
In 1908 the dowager empress fell ill; she was
seventy-four years old. When she felt that her end was near, she seems to have
had the captive emperor Tê Tsung assassinated (at 5 p.m. on November 14th); she
herself died next day (November 15th, 2 p.m.): she was evidently determined
that this man, whom she had ill-treated and oppressed all his life, should not
regain independence. As Tê Tsung had no children, she nominated on the day of
her death the two-year-old prince P'u Yi as emperor (reign name Hsüan-t'ung,
1909-1911).
The fact that another child was to reign and a new
regency to act for him, together with all the failures in home and foreign
policy, brought further strength to the revolutionary party. The government believed
that it could only maintain itself if it allowed Yüan Shih-k'ai, the commander
of the modern troops, to come to power. The chief regent, however, worked
against Yüan Shih-k'ai and dismissed him at the beginning of 1909; Yüan's
supporters remained at their posts. Yüan himself now entered into relations
with the revolutionaries, whose centre was Canton, and whose undisputed leader
was now Sun Yat-sen. At this time Sun and his supporters had already made
attempts at revolution, but without success, as his following was as yet too
small. It consisted mainly of young intellectuals who had been educated in
Europe and America; the great mass of the Chinese people remained unconvinced:
the common people could not understand the new ideals, and the middle class did
not entirely trust the young intellectuals.
The state of China in 1911 was as lamentable as could
be: the European states, Russia, America, and Japan regarded China as a field
for their own plans, and in their calculations paid scarcely any attention to
the Chinese government. Foreign capital was penetrating everywhere in the form
of loans or railway and other enterprises. If it had not been for the mutual
rivalries of the powers, China would long ago have been annexed by one of them.
The government needed a great deal of money for the payment of the war
indemnities, and for carrying out the few reforms at last decided on. In order
to get money from the provinces, it had to permit the viceroys even more
freedom than they already possessed. The result was a spectacle altogether
resembling that of the end of the T'ang dynasty, about A.D. 900: the various
governors were trying to make themselves independent. In addition to this there
was the revolutionary movement in the south.
The government made some concession to the
progressives, by providing the first beginnings of parliamentary rule. In 1910
a national assembly was convoked. It had a Lower House with representatives of
the provinces (provincial diets were also set up), and an Upper House, in which
sat representatives of the imperial house, the nobility, the gentry, and also
the protectorates. The members of the Upper House were all nominated by the
regent. It very soon proved that the members of the Lower House, mainly
representatives of the provincial gentry, had a much more practical outlook
than the routineers of Peking. Thus the Lower House grew in importance, a fact
which, of course, brought grist to the mills of the revolutionary movement.
In 1910 the first risings directed actually against
the regency took place, in the province of Hunan. In 1911 the "railway
disturbances" broke out in western China as a reply of the railway
shareholders in the province of Szechwan to the government decree of nationalization
of all the railways. The modernist students, most of whom were sons of
merchants who owned railway shares, supported the movement, and the government
was unable to control them. At the same time a great anti-Manchu revolution
began in Wuch'ang, one of the cities of which Wuhan, on the Yangtze, now
consists. The revolution was the result of government action against a group of
terrorists. Its leader was an officer named Li Yüan-hung. The Manchus soon had
some success in this quarter, but the other provincial governors now rose in
rapid succession, repudiated the Manchus, and declared themselves independent.
Most of the Manchu garrisons in the provinces were murdered. The governors
remained at the head of their troops in their provinces, and for the moment
made common cause with the revolutionaries, from whom they meant to break free
at the first opportunity. The Manchus themselves failed at first to realize the
gravity of the revolutionary movement; they then fell into panic-stricken
desperation. As a last resource, Yüan Shih-k'ai was recalled (November 10th,
1911) and made prime minister.
Yüan's excellent troops were loyal to his person, and
he could have made use of them in fighting on behalf of the dynasty. But a
victory would have brought no personal gain to him; for his personal plans he
considered that the anti-Manchu side provided the springboard he needed. The
revolutionaries, for their part, had no choice but to win over Yüan Shih-k'ai
for the sake of his troops, since they were not themselves strong enough to get
rid of the Manchus, or even to wrest concessions from them, so long as the
Manchus were defended by Yüan's army. Thus Yüan and the revolutionaries were
forced into each other's arms. He then began negotiations with them, explaining
to the imperial house that the dynasty could only be saved by concessions. The
revolutionaries—apart from their desire to neutralize the prime minister and
general, if not to bring him over to their side—were also readier than ever to
negotiate, because they were short of money and unable to obtain loans from
abroad, and because they could not themselves gain control of the individual
governors. The negotiations, which had been carried on at Shanghai, were broken
off on December 18th, 1911, because the revolutionaries demanded a republic,
but the imperial house was only ready to grant a constitutional monarchy.
Meanwhile the revolutionaries set up a provisional
government at Nanking (December 29th, 1911), with Sun Yat-sen as president and
Li Yüan-hung as vice-president. Yüan Shih-k'ai now declared to the imperial
house that the monarchy could no longer be defended, as his troops were too
unreliable, and he induced the Manchu government to issue an edict on February
12th, 1912, in which they renounced the throne of China and declared the
Republic to be the constitutional form of state. The young emperor of the
Hsüan-t'ung period, after the Japanese conquest of Manchuria in 1931, was
installed there. He was, however, entirely without power during the melancholy
years of his nominal rule, which lasted until 1945.
In 1912 the Manchu dynasty came in reality to its end.
On the news of the abdication of the imperial house, Sun Yat-sen resigned in
Nanking, and recommended Yüan Shih-k'ai as president.
CHAPTER XIV.THE REPUBLIC(1912-1948)
|