A HISTORY OF BABYLON FROM THE FOUNDATION OF THE MONARCHY TO THE PERSIAN CONQUESTCHAPTER V
THE AGE OF HAMMURABI AND ITS INFLUENCE ON LATER PERIODS
OF no other period in the history of Babylon have we so intimate a knowledge as that of the West-Semitic kings under whom the city first attained the rank of capital. It was a time of strenuous growth, in the course of which the long struggle with
regard to language and racial dominance was decided in favour of the Semite. But the victory involved no break of continuity, for all the essential elements of Sumerian culture were preserved, the very length of the
struggle having proved the main factor in securing their survivals. There had been a gradual assimilation on both
sides, though
naturally the Sumerian had the more to give, and, in spite of his political disappearance, he
continued to exert an indirect influence. This he owed in the main to the energy of the Western Semite, who completed
the task of transforming a dying culture, so that in its new embodiment it could be accepted by men
of a newer
race.
Hammurabi's age was one of transition, and we have fortunately recovered a great body of
contemporaneous evidence on which to base an analysis of its social and political structure. On the one hand the great Code
of Laws
supplies us with the state's administrative ideal and standard of justice. On the other
we have the
For the purpose of legislation the Babylonian community
was divided into three main classes or grades of society, which corresponded to well-defined strata
in the social system. The highest or upper class embraced all the officers or ministers attached to the
court, the higher officials and servants of the state, and the owners of considerable landed property. But wealth or
position did not constitute the sole qualification distinguishing the members of the upper class from that
immediately below them. In fact, while the majority of its members , enjoyed these advantages, it was possible for a man
to forfeit
them through his own fault or misfortune and yet to retain his social standing and privileges.
It would seem therefore that the distinction was based on a racial qualification, and that the upper class, or nobles,
as we may perhaps
term them, were men of the predominant race, sprung from the West-Semitic or Amorite stock
The second class in the population comprised the great body of free men who did not come within the ranks of the nobles; in fact, they formed a middle
class between the aristocracy and the slaves. They bore a title which in itself implied a state of inferiority, and though they
were not necessarily poor and could possess slaves and property, they did not share the
privileges of the upper class. It is probable that they represented the subject race, derived in part from the old
Sumerian element in the population, in part from the Semitic strain which had long been settled in Northern Babylonia
and by
intercourse and intermarriage had lost much of its facial purity and independence. The difference,
which divided and
marked off from one another these two great classes of free men in the population, is well illustrated by the
scale of payments as compensation for injury which they were obliged to make or were entitled to receive. Thus if a noble should be guilty of stealing an ox, or other animal, or a boat, which was
private or temple property, he had to pay thirty times its value as compensation; whereas, if the thief were a member
of the middle
class the penalty was reduced to ten times the price, and, should he have no property with
which to pay, he
was put to death. The penalty for manÂslaughter was also less if the assailant
was a man of the middle class; he could obtain a divorce more cheaply,
That a racial distinction underlay the difference
in social
position and standing is suggested by the current penalties for assault, in accordance with which a
noble could
demand an exact retaliation for injuries from one of his own class, whereas he merely paid a money
compensation to any man of the middle class he might have injured. Thus if one noble happened to knock out the eye or the tooth of another, his own eye or his
own tooth was
knocked out in return, and if he broke the limb of one of the members of his own class, he had
his corresponding
limb broken; but, if he knocked out the eye of a member of the middle class, or broke his limb, he was fined one maneh of silver, and for knocking
out the tooth
of such a man, he was fined one-third of a maneh. Other regulations point to a similar
cleavage in the social strata, which can best be explained by a difference in race. Thus if two members of the same class quarrelled and one of them made a peculiarly
improper assault on the other, the assailant was only fined, the fine being larger if the quarrel was between
two nobles. But
if such an assault was made by a member of the middle class upon a noble, the assailant was punished by being publicly beaten in the presence
of the
assembly, when he received sixty stripes from an ox-hide scourge.
The third and lowest class in the community were the slaves, who were owned by both the upper
classes, but were naturally more numerous in the households of the nobles and on their estates. The slave was his master's absolute property, and on the
contract-tablets he is often referred to as "a head," as though he were merely an animal. He constantly changed hands, by sale, bequest, or when temporarily pledged for a
debt. For bad
offences he was liable to severe punishment, such as cutting off the ear, which was the penalty
for denying his
master, or for making an aggravated assault upon a noble. But, on the whole, his lot was not a particularly hard one, for he was a recognized
member
Though the slaves, as a class, had few rights of
their own, there
were regulations in accordance with which, under certain circumstances, they could acquire
them, and even
obtain their freedom. Thus it was possible for an industrious slave, while still in his
master's service, to acquire property of his own, or a slave might inherit wealth from relatives; and, in such circumstances,
he was able with his master's consent to purchase his freedom. Again, if a
slave were captured by the enemy and taken to a foreign land and sold, and were then brought back by his new owner to his own country, he could claim his liberty without having
to pay
compensation to either of his masters. Moreover, a slave could acquire certain rights while still in
slavery. Thus, if the owner of a female slave had begotten children by her, he could not use her as payment
for a debt; and,
in the event of his having done so, he was obliged to ransom her by paying the original amount
of the debt in
money. It was also possible for a male slave, whether owned by a noble or by a member of the middle class, to marry a free woman, and if he did
so his
children were free and did not become the property
The cultivation of the land, which formed the principal
source of the wealth of Babylonia, was carried on mainly by slave labour, under the control of the
two upper
classes of the population. The land itself was largely in the hands of the crown, the temples, and the great nobles and merchants who were landed proprietors; and, including that still in communal or tribal possession, a very large
proportion was cultivated on lease. The usual practice in hiring land for cultivation was for the tenant to pay his rent
in kind, by
assigning a certain proportion of the crop, generally a third or a half, to the owner, who
advanced the seed-corn. The tenant was bound to till the land and raise a crop, and should he neglect to do so he
had to pay the
owner what was reckoned as the average rent of the land, and he had also to break up the land and plough it before handing it back. Elaborate
regulations were in force to adjust the landowner's duties and responsibilities on the one hand, and what was
due to him from
his tenant on the other. As the rent of a field was usually reckoned at harvest, and its
amount depended on
the size of the crop, it would have been unfair that damage to the crop from flood or storm should have been made up by the tenant; such a loss was shared equally by the owner of the field and
the farmer, though, if the latter had already paid his
rent at the time
the damage occurred, he could not make a claim for repayment. There is evidence that disputes were frequent not only between farmers and
landowners, but also between farmers and shepherds, for the latter, when attempting to find pasture for their flocks,
often allowed
their sheep to feed off the farmers' fields in spring. For such cases a scale of compensation was fixed. If the damage was done in the early spring, when the plants were still small, the farmer
harvested the crop and received a price in kind as compensation from the shepherd. But if it occurred later in the
year, when the
sheep had been brought in from the meadows and turned on to the common land by the city-gate,
the damage was
heavier; in such a case the shepherd had to take over the crop and compensate the farmer
heavily.
The king himself was a very large owner of cattle and sheep, and he levied tribute on the flocks and
herds of his
subjects. The owners were bound to bring the young cattle and lambs, that were due from them, to
the central
town of the district in which they dwelt, and they were then collected and added to the royal
flocks and herds.
If the owners attempted to hold back any that were due as tribute, they were afterwards forced to incur the extra expense and trouble of driving the
beasts to Babylon.
The flocks and herds owned by the king and the great temples were probably enormous, and yielded a considerable revenue in themselves apart
from the tribute
and taxes levied upon private owners. Shepherds and herdsmen were placed in charge of them, and they were divided into groups under head-men,
who arranged
the districts in which the herds and flocks were to be grazed. The king received regular reports
from his chief
shepherds and herdsmen, and it was the duty of the governors of the larger towns and districts
of Babylonia
to make tours of inspection and see that due care was taken of the royal flocks. The
sheep-shearing for all the flocks that were pastured near the capital took place in Babylon, and the king used to send out summonses
to his chief shepherds to inform them of the day when the shearing would take place. Separate flocks,
In the regulation of the pastoral and agricultural life of the
community, custom played a very important part, and this was recognized and enforced by royal authority. Carelessness in looking after cattle was punished by fine, but the owner was not held
responsible for damage unless negligence could be proved on his part. Thus a bull might go wild at any time and
gore a man, who
would have no redress against its owner, but if the beast was known to be vicious, and its owner had not blunted its horns nor shut it up, he was
obliged to pay compensation for damage. On the other hand, the owner of cattle or asses, who had hired them
out, could exact
compensation for the loss or ill-treatment of his beasts. These were framed on the principle that the hirer was responsible only for damage or loss
which he could reasonably have prevented. If, for example, a lion killed a hired ox or ass in the open country,
or if an ox was killed by lightning, the loss fell upon the owner and not on the man who had hired the beast. But if the hirer killed the ox through carelessness or by beating it unmercifully, or if the beast broke its
leg while in
his charge, he had to restore to the owner another ox in its place. For less serious damage to
the beast the
hirer paid compensation on a fixed scale. It
is clear that such regulations merely gave the royal sanction to long-established custom.
Both for looking after their herds and for the cultivation
of their estates the landed proprietors depended to a great extent upon hired herdsmen and farmers; and any dishonesty on the part of the latter with
regard to cattle,
provender, or seed-corn was severely punished. A theft of provender, for example, had to be made
good, and the
culprit ran the additional risk of having his hands cut off. Heavy compensation was exacted from any man, who, for his own profit, hired out oxen which
had
In the semi-tropical climate of Babylonia the
canals played a
vitally important part for the successful prosecution of agriculture, and it
was to the royal interest to see that their channels were kept in a proper state of repair and cleaned out at regular intervals. There
is evidence
that nearly every king of the First Dynasty of Babylon cut new canals and extended the system ofirrigation and transport by water that he had inherited. The rich silt carried down by the rivers was
deposited partly in the canals, especially in those sections nearer the main stream, with the result that the bed of a
canal was
constantly in process of being raised. Every year it was necessary to dig this deposit out and pile
it upon the banks. Every year the banks rose higher and higher, until a point was reached when the labour involved in getting rid of the silt became greater
than that
required for cutting a new channel. Hence sections of a canal were constantly being recut alongside
the old channel, and it is probable that many of the canals, the cutting of which is commemorated in the texts, were really reconstructions of older streams, the beds
of which had become hopelessly silted up.
At the present day the traveller in certain parts
of Babylonia
comes across the raised embankments of old canals extending across the plain within a short
distance of each other, and their parallel course is to be explained by the process of recutting, which was put off as
long as possible, but was at last necessitated by the growing height of the banks. As the bed of a canal
gradually rose too, the high banks served the purpose of retaining the stream, and these were often washed away by the flood-water which came down from the hills in
spring. An interesting letter has been preserved, that was written by Hammurabi's grandson, Abi-eshu, who describes a sudden rise of this sort in the level of the Irnina
Canal so that it
overflowed its banks. At the time the king was building a palace in the city of Kar-Irnina,
which was
supplied by the Irnina Canal, and every year a certain amount of work was put into the building.
At the time
the letter was written little more than a third of the year's work had been done, when the
building-operations were stopped by flood, the canal having overflowed its banks so that the water rose right
up to the
town-wall.
It was the duty of the local governors to see that the canals were kept in good repair, and they had
the power of
requisitioning labour from the inhabitants of' villages and the owners of land situated on or near
the banks. In
return, the villagers had the right of fishing in the waters of a canal along the section in their
charge, and any poaching by other villagers in their part of the stream was strictly forbidden. On one occasion in
the reign of
Samsu-iluna, Hammurabi's son, fishermen from the village of Rabim went down in their boats to
the district of
Shakanim, and caught fish there contrary to local custom. So the inhabitants of Shakanim complained
to the king of this infringement of their rights, and he sent a palace-official to the authorities of
Sippar, in the jurisdiction of which the villages in question lay, with instructions to inquire into the matter and
take steps to
prevent any poaching in the future. Fishing by line and net was a regular industry, and the
preservation of rights in local waters was jealously guarded.
The larger canals were fed directly from the river, especially along the Euphrates, whose banks were
lower than those
of the swifter Tigris. But along the latter river, and also along the banks of the canals, it
will be obvious that some means had to be employed to raise the water for purposes of irrigation from the main
One of these must certainly have corresponded to a very primitive arrangement that is in general use
at the present day in Mesopotamia, particularly along the Tigris, where the banks are high and steep. A recess or
cutting with perpendicular sides is driven into the bank, and a wooden spindle is supported on struts in a
horizontal position over the recess, which resembles a well with one side opening on to the river. A rope running over the
spindle is fastened to a skin in which the water is raised from the river, being drawn up by horses, donkeys, or
cattle harnessed to the other end of the rope. To empty the skin by hand into the irrigation channel would, of
course, entail considerable time and labour, and, to avoid this necessity, an ingenious contrivance is employed.
The
On the Euphrates, where the river-banks are lower, a simple form of water-wheel was probably in use
then as it is
today, wherever there was sufficient current to work one. And the advantage of this form of machine is that, so long as it is in order, it can be
unlocked at will and kept working without supervision day and night. The wheel is formed of stripped boughs and branches nailed together, with spokes joining the
outer rims to a
roughly hewn axle. Around the outer rim are tied a series of rough earthenware cups or bottles, and a few rude paddles are fixed to the wheel,
projecting beyond the rim. The wheel is then set up in place near the bank of the river, its axle resting on
pillars of rough masonry. The current turns the wheel, and the bottles, dipping below the surface, are laised up
full, and empty
their water into a wooden trough at the top. The banks of the Euphrates are usually sloping, and the water is conducted from the trough to the
fields along a
small aqueduct or earthen embankment. Such wheels today are usually set up where there is a
slight drop in the
river-bed and the water runs swiftly over shallows. In order to span the difference in level between the fields and the summer height of the
stream the wheels
are often huge contrivances, and their rough construction causes them to creak and groan as they turn with the current. In a convenient place in the river several of these are sometimes set up side by
side, and their
noise when at work can be heard at a great distance.
It is not unlikely that the later Sumerians had already evolved these primitive forms of
irrigation-machine, and that the Babylonians of the First Dynasty merely inherited them and passed them on to their successors. When once invented they were incapable of very great improvement. In the one the skin must always remain a skin; in the other the wheel must always be lightly constructed of boughs, or the
strength of the current would not suffice to turn it. We have seen reason to believe that, in the palace of
Nebuchadnezzar II. at Babylon, the triple well in the north-west corner may be best explained as having formed the water-supply for a hydraulic machine, consisting of an
endless chain of buckets passing over a great wheel. Such is a very common form of raising water in Babylonia at the present day. It is true that in some of these machines the wheel for the buckets is still geared
by means of
rough wooden cogs to the long pole or winch, turned by beasts, who move round in a circle. But
it is very
unlikely that the early Babylonians had evolved the principle of the cogged wheel, and it was
probably not till the period of the later Assyrian empire that bronze was so plentiful that it could have been
used in
sufficient quantity for buckets on an endless chain. There seems reason to believe that Sennacherib
himself
The manner in which the agricultural implements employed in early Babylonia have survived to the present day is well illustrated by their form of
plough, which closely resembles that still in use in parts of Syria. We have no representation of the plough of
Before ploughing and sowing his land the Babylonian farmer prepared it for irrigation by dividing it up
into a number of
small squares or oblong patches, each separated from the others by a low bank of earth. Some of the banks, that ran lengthways through the field, were made into small channels, the ends of
which were
connected with his main irrigation-stream. No gates nor sluices were employed, and, when he
wished to water one of his fields, he simply broke away the bank opposite one of his small channels and let the
water
He could then repeat the process with the next square, and so on, afterwards returning to the main channel and stopping the flow of water by blocking
up the hole he
had made in the bank. Such is the present process "of irrigation in Mesopotamia, and
there is no doubt that it was adopted by the early Babylonians. It was extremely simple, but needed care and
vigilance, especially when water was being carried into several parts of an estate at once. Moreover, one main
channel often supplied the fields of several farmers, and, in return for his share of the water, it was the duty
of each man to
keep its banks, where it crossed his land, in repair. If he failed to do so and the water forced
a breach and
flooded his neighbour's field, he had to pay compensation in kind for any crop that was ruined, and, if he could not pay, his goods were sold, and
his neighbours,
whose fields had been damaged, shared the proceeds of the sale. Similarly, if a farmer left
his water
running and forgot to shut it off, he had to pay compensation for any damage it might do to a neighbouring
crop.
The date-palm formed the chief secondary source of the country's wealth, for it grew luxuriantly in
the alluvium
and supplied the Babylonians with one of their principal articles of diet. From it, too, they made a fermented wine, and a species of flour for baking; its sap yielded palm-sugar, and its fibrous
bark was
suitable for weaving ropes, while its trunk furnished a light but tough building-material. The early Babylonian
kings encouraged the laying out of date-plantations and the planting of
gardens and orchards; and special regulations were made with that object in view. For a man could obtain a field for the purpose
without paying a yearly rent. He could plant and tend it for four years, and in the fifth year of his tenancy
the original owner of the land took half the garden in payment, while the planter kept the other half for himself. Care was taken to see that the bargain was properly carried out, for, if a bare patch had been left in
the plantation,
it was reckoned in the planter's half; and should the tenant neglect the trees during his
first four years of occupation, he was still liable to plant the whole plot without receiving his half of it, and he
had to pay
compensation in addition, which varied in amount according to the original condition of the
land. In this way
the authorities ensured that land should not be taken over and allowed to deteriorate. For the hire of a plantation the rent was fixed at
two-thirds of its produce, the tenant providing all labour and
supplying the necessary irrigation-water.
From the royal letters of the period of the First Dynasty we know that the canals were not only used for irrigation, but also as water-ways for transport. The letters contain directions for the bringing of corn, dates, sesame-seed, and wood to Babylon, and we also know that wool and oil were carried in bulk by water. For transport of heavy goods on the Tigris and Euphrates it is possible that rafts, floated on inflated skins, were used from an early period, though the earliest evidence we have of their employment is furnished by the bas-reliefs from Nineveh. Such rafts have survived to the present day, and they are specially adapted for the transport of heavy materials, for they are carricd down by the current, and are kept in the main stream by means of huge sweeps or oars. Being formed only of logs of wood and skins, they arc not costly, for wood was plentiful in the upper course of the rivers. At the end of the journey, after the goods were landed, they were broken up, the logs being sold at a profit, and the skins, after being deflated, were packed on donkeys to return up stream by caravan. The use of such keleks can only have been general when through river communication was general, but, since we know that Hammurabi included Assyria within his dominions, it is not impossible that they may date from at least as early a period as the First Dynasty. For purely local traffic in small bulk the gufa, or light coracle, may have been used in Babylonia at this time, for its representation on the Assyrian monuments corresponds exactly with its structure at the present time as used on the lower Tigris and Euphrates. The gufa is forme of wicker-work coated with bitumen, but some of those represented on the sculptures from Nineveh appear to have been covered with skins as in the description of Herodotus. In the texts and inscriptions of the early period (ships are referred to, and these were undoubtedly
the only class
of vessels employed on the canals for conveying supplies in bulk by water. The
size of such ships, or barges, was reckoned by the amount of grain they were capable of carrying, measured by the gur, the largest measure of capacity. We find vessels of very different size referred to, varying from five
to seventy-five gur and over. The larger class probably resembled the sailing barges and ferry-boats in use today, which are built of heavy
timbers and have flat
It is probable that there were regular officials, under the king's control, who collected dues and looked after the water-transport in the separate sections of the river, or canal, on which they were stationed. It would have been their duty to report any damage or defect in the channel to the king, who would send orders to the local governor that the necessary repairs should be put in hand. One of Hammurabi's letters deals with the blocking of a canal at Erech, about which he had received such reports. The dredging already undertaken had not been thoroughly done, so that the canal had soon silted up again and boats were prevented from reaching the city ; in his letter Hammurabi sent pressing orders that the canal was to be rendered navigable within three days. Special regulations were also in force with regard to the respective responsibilities of boat-owners, boatmen and their clients. If a boatÂman hired a boat from its owner, he was held responsible for it, and had to replace it should it be lost or sunk ; but if he refloated it, he had only to pay the owner half its value for the damage it had sustained. Boatmen were also responsible for the safety of goods, such as corn, wool, oil or dates, which they had undertaken to carry for hire, and they had to make good any total loss due to their own carelessness. Collisions between two vessels were also provided for, and should one of the boats have been moored at the time, the boatman of the other vessel had to pay compensation for the boat that was sunk as well as for the lost cargo, the owner of the latter estimating its value upon oath. Many cases in the courts probably arose out of loss or damage to goods in course of transport by water. The commercial activities of Babylon at the time
of the First
Dynasty led to a considerable growth in the size of the larger cities, which ceased to be
merely local centres of distribution and began to engage in commerce farther afield. Between Babylonia and Elam close commercial relations had long been maintained, but Hammurabi's western conquests opened up new markets to the merchants of his capital. The great
trade-route up the Euphrates and into Syria was no longer blocked by military outposts and fortifications, placed
there in the vain attempt to keep back the invasion of Amorite tribes; and the trade in pottery with Carchemish,
of which we
have evidence under the later kings of the First Dynasty, is significant of the
new relations established between Babylonia and the West. The great merchants were, as a body, members of the
upper class, and
while they themselves continued to reside in Babylon, they employed traders who carried their
goods abroad for
them by caravan.
Even Hammurabi could not entirely guarantee the safety of such traders, for attacks by brigands
were then as common in the Nearer East as at the present day; and there was always the additional risk that a
caravan might be captured by the enemy, if it ventured too near a hostile frontier. In such circumstances the king
saw to it that
the loss of the goods was not borne by the agent, who had already risked his life and liberty
in undertaking
their transport. For, if such an agent had been forced in the course of his journey to give up
some of the
goods he was carrying, he had to specify the exact amount on oath on his return, and he was then acquitted of all responsibility. But if it could be proved before the elders of the city that he had attempted to cheat his employer by misappropriating money or goods to his own use, he was obliged to
pay the
merchant three times the value of the goods he had taken. The law was not one-sided and afforded the agent equal protection in relation to his more
powerful employer; for should the latter be convicted of an attempt to defraud his agent, by denying that the due amount had been returned to him, he had to pay
his agent as
compensation six times the amount in dispute. The merchant always advanced the goods or money with which to trade, and the fact that he could, if
he wished to
do so, fix his own profit at double the value of the capital, is an indication of the very
satisfactory returns obtained at this period from foreign commerce. But the more usual practice was for merchant and
trader to share the profits between them, and, in the event of the latter making such bad bargains that there was
a loss on his
journey, he had to refund to the merchant the full value of the goods lie had received. At
the time of the
First Dynasty asses and donkeys were the beasts of burden employed for carrying
merchandise, for the horse was as yet a great rarity and was not in general use in Babylonia until after the Kassite conquest.
A large number of the First Dynasty contracts relate to commercial journeys of this sort, and
record the terms of the bargains entered into between the interested parties. Such partnerships were
sometimes concluded for a single journey, but more often for longer periods of time. The merchant always
demanded a properly executed receipt for the money or goods he advanced to the trader, and the latter received one
for any deposit
or pledge he might have made in token of his good faith. In reckoning their accounts on the conclusion of a journey, only such amounts as were specified in the receipts were regarded as legal
obligations, and, if either party had omitted to obtain his proper documents, he did so at his own risk. The market-places of the capital and the larger towns
must have been
the centres where such business arrangements were transacted, and official scribes were probably
always in attendance to draw up the terms of any bargain in the presence of other merchants and traders, who acted
as witnesses.
These had their names enumerated at the close of the document, and since they were chosen from loeal residents, some were always at hand to
testify in case of any subsequent dispute.
The town-life in Babylonia at this time must have had many features in common with that of any provincial
town in Mesopotamia today, except that the paternal government of the First Dynasty
undoubtedly saw to it that the streets were kept clean, and made strenuous efforts to ensure that private houses
should be soundly built and maintained in proper repair. We have already followed out the lines of some of the streets in ancient Babylon, and noted
that, while the
We have recovered from contemporary documents a very full picture of family life in early
Babylonia, for the duties of the separate members of a family to one
The law gave the wife ample protection, and in the case of the husband's desertion allowed her, under
certain conditions, to become the legal wife of another man. If the husband wilfully deserted her and left his
city under no
compulsion, she might remarry and he could not reclaim her on his return. But if his desertion
was involuntary,
as in the case of a man taken in battle and carried off as a prisoner, this rule did not apply; and the wife was allowed to shape her action during his absence in accordance with the condition of her husband's
affairs. The regulations in such a case were extraordinarily in favour of the woman. If the husband was possessed
of property
sufficient to maintain the wife during the period of his captivity, she had no excuse for
remarriage;
Such regulations throw an interesting light on the position of the married woman in the Babylonian community, which was not only unexampled in antiquity but compares favourably, in point of
freedom and independence, with her status in many countries of modern Europe. Still more remarkable were the privileges capable of attainment by unmarried women of the upper class, who in certain circumstances
were entitled to
hold property in their own names and engage in commercial undertakings. To secure such a position a woman took vows, by which she became a member of a class of votaries attached to one of
the chief
temples in Babylon, Sippar, or another of the great cities. The duties of such women
were not sacerdotal, and, though they generally lived
together in a special building, or convent, attached to the temple, they enjoyed a position of great influence and
independence in the community. A votary could possess property in her own
name, and on taking her vows was provided with a portion by her father, exactly as though she were being given in marriage. This was vested
in herself,
and did not become the property of her order, nor of the temple to which she was attached; it
was devoted
entirely to her maintenance, and after her father's death, her brothers looked after her
interest, and she could farm the property out. Upon her death her portion returned to her own family, unless her father assigned her the privilege of bequeathing
it; but any
property she inherited she could bequeath, and she had not to pay taxes on it. She had
consider^ able freedom, could engage in commerce on her ownt account, and, should she desire to do so, could
leave! the convent and contract a form of marriage.
While securing her these privileges, the vows she took entailed corresponding responsibilities. Even
when married, a
votary was still obliged to remain a virgin, and, should her husband desire children, she eould
not bear them
herself, but must provide him with a maid or coneubine. But, in spite of this disability, she
was secured in
her position as the permanent head of the household. The concubine, though she might bear the husband children, was always the wife's inferior,
and should she
attempt to put herself on a level with the votary, the latter could brand her and put her with
the female
slaves; while in the event of the concubine proving barren, she eould be sold. Unmarried
votaries, too, could live in houses of their own and dispose of their time and money in their own way. But a high standard of commercial and social morality was
expeeted from them, and severe penalties were imposed for its infringement. No votary, for example, was permitted to open a beer-shop, and should she even enter
one, she ran the risk of being put to death. An unmarried votary also enjoyed the status of a married woman,
and the penalty
for slandering one was branding in the forehead. That the social position
enjoyed by a votary was
It is a striking fact that women of an Eastern race should have achieved such a position of
independence at the beginning of the second millennium. The explanation is perhaps
to be sought in the great part already played by commerce in Babylonian life. Among contemporary races, occupied mainly by agriculture
and war,
woman's activity was necessarily restricted to the rearing of children and to the internal economy of
the household.
But with the growth of Babylonian trade and commercial enterprise, it would seem that the demand arose, on the part of women of the upper
class, to take
part in activities in which they considered themselves capable of joining. The success of the experiment was doubtless due in part to the high standard of morality exacted, and in part to the
prestige conferred by association with the religious cult.
The administration of justice at the period of the First Dynasty was carried out by duly appointed y courts of-law under the supervision of the king. The judges were appointed by the crown, and a check was put upon any arbitrary administration of the law by
the fact that
the elders of the city sat with them and assisted them in hearing and sifting evidence. When once a judgment had been given and recorded, it was irrevocable, and if any
judge attempted to alter such a decision, he was expelled from his judgment-seat and debarred from exercising judicial functions in the future.
The regulation
was probably intended to prevent the possibility of subsequent bribery; and,
if a litigant considered that justice had not been done, it was always open to him to appeal to the king. Hammurabi's letters
prove that he
exercised strict supervision, not only over the cases decided in the capital, but also over those
which were tried
in the other great cities of Babylonia, and it is clear that he Attempted to stamp out corruption on the part of all those invested with authority. On
one occasion he
had been informed of a case of bribery in the town of Dur-gurgurri, and he at once ordered
the governor of
the district to investigate the charge and send the guilty parties to Babylon for punishment.
The bribe, too,
was to be confiscated and despatched to Babylon under seal, a wise provision that would have tended to discourage those inclined to tamper with
the course of
justice, while at the same time it enriched the state. The king probably tried all cases of appeal in person, when it was possible; but in distant cities
he deputed
this duty to local officials. Many of the cases that came before him arose from the extortions of money-lenders, and the king had no mercy when fraud on their part was proved.
The relations maintained by the king with the numerous classes of the priesthood was also very
close, and the
control he exercised over the chief priests and their subordinates appears to have been as
effective as that he maintained over the judicial authorities throughout the country. Under the Sumerians there had always been a tendency on the part of the more powerful members of the hierarchy to usurp the prerogatives of the crown, but this danger appears to have been fully discounted under the rule of the Western Semites. One important section of the priestly body were the astrologers, whose duty it
probably was to make periodical reports to the king on the conjunctions and movements of the heavenly bodies, with the object of ascertaining whether they
portended good or evil to the state. The later Assyrian practice, may well have had its origin at this period, and we
may conclude
that the regulation of the calendar was carried out in accordance with such advice. One of Hammurabi's
letters has come down to us in which he writes to inform Sin-idinnam, his local governor of Larsa,
that it had been decided to insert an intercalary month in the calendar. He writes that, as the year, that is the
ln the naming of the year the priesthood must also have played an important part, since the majority
of the events from
which the years were named were of a religious character. The system, which was inherited from the Sumerians, cannot have been a very
convenient one, and no doubt it owed its retention to the sanctity of the religious rites and associations attaching
to it. There can
be little doubt that, normally, the naming of the year took place at the New Year's Feast, and,
when the event commemorated in the formula was the installation
of a chief priest or the dedication of temple-furniture, the royal act, we may assume, was performed
on the day the
year was named. Often merely a provisional title was adopted from
the preceding formula, and then perhaps no ceremony of naming was held, unless in the course of it a great victory, or other important occurrence, was commemorated by the renaming of the year. The king must have consulted with his
priestly advisers before the close of the old year, and have settled
on the new formula in good time to allow of its announcement in the outlying districts of the
kingdom.
Another important religious class at this period
was the guild of soothsayers, and they also appear to have been direetly under the royal control. This we
gather from a letter of Ammi-ditana, one of the later kings of the First Dynasty, written to three high officials
of Sippar,
which illustrates the nature of their duties and the sort of occasion on which they were called upon
to perform
them. It had come to the king's knowledge that there was a scarcity of corn in Shagga, and
since that town
was in the administrative district of Sippar, he wrote to the officials concerned ordering them to
send a supply thither. But, before the corn was brought into the city, they were to consult the soothsayers, in
order to
ascertain whether the omens were favourable. The method of inquiry is not specified, but it was
probably liver-divination, which was in common use during all periods. Only if the omens proved
favourable, was the corn to be brought into the town, and we may conclude that the king took this precaution as he feared
that the scarcity of corn in Shagga was due to the anger of some local deity. The astrologers would be able to
ascertain the facts, and, in the event of their reporting unfavourably, no doubt
the serviees of the local priesthood would have been called in.
We have already seen that flocks and herds which were owned by the great temples were sometimes pastured
with those of the king, and there is abundant evidence that the king also superintended the
collection of temple-revenues along with his own. Collectors of both secular and ecclesiastical tribute sent
reports directly to the king, and, if there was any deficit in the supply expected from a collector, he had to make it up himself. From one of Hammurabi's letters, for example, we gather that two landowners, or moneylenders,
had lent money or advanced seed-corn to certain farmers near the towns of Dur-gurgurri and Bakhabu and along the Tigris, and in settlement of their
claims had seized the crops, refusing to pay the proportion due to Bit-il-kitti the great temple of the Sun-god at Larsa. The governor of Larsa, the principal city in
the district,
had rightly, as the representative of the palace, caused the tax-collector to make up the deficiency,
but Hammurabi,
on receiving the subordinate officer's complaint, referred the matter back to
the governor, and we may infer from similar cases that the defaulting parties had to make good the loss and submit to fines or
punishment. The document throws an interesting light on the methods of government administration, and the manner in which the king gave personal supervision
to the
smallest details.
It will be obvious that for the administration of
the country a
large body of officials were required, and of their number two classes, of a semi-military
character, enjoyed the king's special favour and protection. They were placed in charge of public works and looked
after and
controlled the public slaves, and they probably alsohad a good deal to do with the collection of the revenue. As payment for their duties, they were each granted land with a house and garden; they were assigned
sheep and cattle
to stock their land, and in addition they received a regular salary. They were, in a sense,
personal retainers of the king, and were liable to be sent at any moment on a special mission. Disobedience
was severely
punished, for if such an officer, when detailed for special service, hired a substitute, he was
liable to be put to death and the substitute could take his office. Sometimes an officer was sent to take charge of a
distant garrison for a long period, and when this was done his home duties were performed by another man, who temporarily
occupied his house and land, and gave it back to the officer on his return. If the officer had a
son old enough
to perform the duty in his father's absence, he war allowed to do s ; and, if he was too young,
his maintenance
was paid for out of the estate. Should the officer fail to arrange, before his departure, for the proper cultivation of his land and the discharge of
his local
duties, another could take his place after the lapse
of a year, and on his return he could not reclaim
his land or
office. When on garrison duty, or on special service, he ran the risk of capture by the enemy,
and in that event
his ransom was assured. For if his own means did not suffice, the sum had to be paid from the treasury of the local temple, and in the last
resort by the state. It was specially enacted that his land, garden, and house were in no case to be sold to pay for his ransom. They were inalienably attached to
the office he
held, which appears to have been entailed in the male line, since he was precluded from
bequeathing any of the property to his wife or daughter. They could only pass from him and his male issue through neglect or disobedience.
It is not improbable that the existence of this specially favoured class of officer dates back to
the earliest
settlement of the Western Semites in Babylonia. The first of their number may well have been
personal retainers and followers of Sumu-abum, the founder of the dynasty. Originally soldiers, they were
probably assigned lands throughout the country in return for their services to the king, and they continued to
serve him by
maintaining order and upholding his authority. In the course of time specified duties were
assigned to them, but they retained their privileges, and they must have remained a very valuable body of officers, on whose personal loyalty the king could always rely. In the case of war, they may have assisted in
mobilization; for the army was probably raised on a territorial basis, much on the lines of the corvee for public works which was under their control.
By contemporary documents of the period much light is thrown on other classes of the population,
but, as they
were all connected with various departments in the commercial or agricultural life of the
community, it will be unnecessary to describe them in further detail. One class perhaps deserves mention, the surgeons,
since lack of professional skill was rather heavily penalized. For if a surgeon, when called in by a
noble, carried out
an operation so unskilfully as to cause his death or inflict a permanent injury upon him, such
as the loss of
an eye, the punishment was amputation of
In the religious sphere, the rise of Babylon to the position of capital led to a number of important changes, and to a revision of the Babylonian
pantheon. Marduk, the god of Babylon, from being a comparatively obscure
city-god, underwent a transformation in proportion to the increase in his city's importance. The achievements and attributes of Enlil, the chief Sumerian deity, were ascribed to him, and the old Sumerian sagas and legends, particularly those of
the creation of
the world, were rewritten in this new spirit by the Babylonian priesthood. The beginning of the process may be accurately dated to the year of
Hammurabi's conquest of Rim-Sin and his subsequent control of Nippur, the
ancient centre of the old Sumerian faith. It does not appear that the earlier Semites, when they conquered that city, had ever attempted to modify the old traditions they found there, or
to appropriate
them for their local gods. But a new spirit was introduced with the triumph of the Western Semites. The Sumerians were then a dying race, and the gradual disappearance of their language as a
living tongue was
accompanied by a systematic translation, and a partial transformation, of their sacred literature. Enlil could not be entirely ousted from the
position he had so long enjoyed, but Marduk became his greater son. The younger god is represented as winning his position by his own valour, in coming to the help
of the older
gods when their very existence was threatened by the dragons of chaos; and, having slain the
monster, of the deep, he is portrayed as creating the universe from her severed body. The older legends, no doubt, continued to be treasured in the ancient cult-centres of the land, but the Babylonian versions, under
royal sanction
and encouragement, tended to gain wide recognition and popularity.
Under the later kings of the First Dynasty a great impetus was also given to all branches of literary
activity. The old Sumerian language still bulked largely in the phraseology of legal and commercial documents, as
well as in the
purely religious literature of the country. And, to aid them in their study of the ancient
texts, the Semitic
scribes undertook a systematic compilation of explanatory lists of words and ideograms, the
earliest form of dictionary, which continued in use into the Assyrian and Neo-Babylonian periods. The Sumerian texts, too, were copied out and furnished with
inter-linear Semitic translations. The astronomical and astrological studies and
records of the Sumerian priests were taken over, and great collections were compiled in combination with the early Akkadian records that
had come down
to them. A study of the Babylonian literature affords striking proof that the
semitizing of the country led to no break, nor set-back, in Babylonian, culture. The older texts and traditions were taken over in bulk, and, except where the rank or
position of Marduk was affected, little change or modification was made. The Semitic scribes no doubt developed their inheritance, but expansion took place on the
old lines.
In commercial life, too, Sumerian customs remained to a great extent unaltered. Taxes, rent, and prices continued to be paid in kind, and though the
talent, maneh, and shekel were in use as metal weights, and silver was in partial circulation, no true currency
was developed.
In the sale of land, for example, even during the period of the Kassite kings, the purchase price was settled in shekel-weights of silver, but
very little
metal actually changed hands. Various items were exchanged against the land, and these, in
addition to corn, the principal medium of exchange, included slaves, animals, weapons, garments, etc., the
value of each item being reckoned on the same silver basis, until the agreed purchase-price was made up. The early Semitic Babylonian, despite his commercial
activity, did not advance beyond the transition stage between pure barter and a regular currency.
One important advantage conferred by the Western Semite on the country of his adoption was an
increase in the area of its commercial relations and a political expansion to the north and west. He systematized
its laws, and
placed its internal administration on a wider and more uniform basis. But the greatest and most far-reaching change of the Hammurabi period was
that the common
speech of the whole of Babylonia became Semitic, as did the dominant racial element in the population. And it was thanks to this fact that all subsequent invasions of the country failed to alter
the main
features in her civilization. Such alien strains were absorbed in process of time, and, though they undoubtedly introduced fresh blends into the racial mixture, the Semitic element triumphed, and
continued to receive reinforcements from the parent stock. The Sumerian race and language appear to have survived longest in the extreme south of the country, and we shall see that the rise of the Sea-Country kings
may perhaps be
regarded as their last effective effort in the political sphere.
THE CLOSE OF THE FIRST DYNASTY OF BABYLON AND THE KINGS FROM THE COUNTRY OF THE SEA
|
||||||||||||||