READING HALLTHE DOORS OF WISDOM |
GERMANY AND THE WESTERN EMPIRE
CHAPTER XVIII. FEUDALISM.
THE feudal organization of
state and society is the dominant fact of medieval history on its
institutional side quite as much as the city-state is the dominant fact of
ancient history from the institutional point of view. Such dominant facts
cannot be restricted chronologically to a definite period; they arise gradually
and give way slowly to new conditions. But it may be said in a general way
that the epoch when feudalism formed most characteristically the centre of political and social arrangements
comprised the eleventh and twelfth centuries. From the thirteenth century
onwards feudal law continued to be appealed to and feudal principles were
sometimes formulated even more sharply than before, but the modern State was
beginning to assert itself in most European countries in an unmistakable manner
and its influence began to modify the fundamental conceptions of feudalism. In
our survey of feudal society we shall therefore look for illustrations mainly
to the period between the years 1000 and 1200, though sometimes we may have to
draw on the materials presented by thirteenth century documents.
The essential relations of
feudalism are as unfamiliar to us as the conception of the city-state. In one
sense it may be defined as an arrangement of society on the basis of contract.
Contracts play an important part in the business life of our time, but we do
not think of the commonwealth as based on leases; we do not consider a nation
primarily as a number of lords and tenants; we do not take the status of every
single person to be determined by obligations as to land; we do not assume that
the notions of sovereignty and of citizenship depend on the stipulations of an
express or implied contract. In the medieval period under consideration, on the
other hand, it would be easy to deduce all forms of political organization and
of social inter-course from feudal contract. The status of a person depended in
every way on his position on the land, and on the other hand, land-tenure
determined political rights and duties. The public organization of England, for
example, was derived from the fact that all the land in the country was held by
a certain number of tenants-in-chief, including ecclesiastical incorporations
and boroughs, from the king, while all the rest of the population consisted
either of under-tenants or of persons settled on the land of some tenant and
amenable to jurisdiction through the latter. In other West-European countries
the distribution of the people was more intricate and confused because there
had been no wholesale conquest capable of reducing conditions to uniformity,
but the fundamental facts were the same. Every West-European country was
arranged on the basis of feudal land-tenure.
The acts constituting the
feudal contract were called homagium and investitura. The tenant
had to appear in person before the lord surrounded by his court, to kneel
before him and to put his folded hands into the hand of the lord, saying: “I
swear to be faithful and attached to you as a man should be to his lord”. He
added sometimes: “I will do so as long as I am your man and as I hold your
land”. To this act of homage corresponded the ‘investiture’ by the lord,
who delivered to his vassal a flag, a staff, a charter or some other symbol of
the property conceded. There were many variations according to localities and,
of course, the ceremony differed in the case of a person of base status. Yet
even a villein received his yard-land
or oxgang from the steward of a
lord after swearing an oath of fealty and in the form of an ‘admittance’ by the
staff, of which a record was kept in the rolls of the manorial court : hence
the copyhold tenure of English law.
Tenure conditioned by service
was called the feudum,
fief, Lehn, but sometimes these terms were restricted to the better class of
such estates, those held by military service, while the lands for which rents
and labor-services were rendered were described
as censivae,
in England socagia.
The holdings of villeins or rustics (Bauern, roturiers) were deemed in law to be at the will of the
lord, but in practice were protected by the local custom and generally
subjected to quasi-legal rules of possession and inheritance. Although feudal tenure
was certainly the most common mode of holding land, it was not the only one. In
France and Germany there were still many survivals of allodial right, that is
of complete ownership, not subject to any conditions of service or payment. In
fact, while in northern France there obtained the rule nulle terre sans seigneur,
that is, the doctrine that all estates were held by feudal law under lords, in
southern France, the territory of written law based on Roman books, the
contrary was expressed in the words nul seigneur sans titre: no lordship was recognize
unless proof of title were forthcoming. Many documents show the constant spread
of feudal tenure at the expense of the allodial : the process of feudalization
is, e.g., forcibly illustrated by the inquest as to land-tenures made in 1272
and 1273 by order of King Edward I in Aquitaine : it testified to all sorts of
variations in the mode of holding land in these parts; claims to allodial
rights are often recorded. But the tendency of the inquest is to impose the
burden of services as widely as possible. The circumstances in which the
process of feudalization was going on may be illustrated by the following tale
of a Flemish chronicle (Lambert d'Ardre,
quoted by Luchaire,
Manuel, 151). In the beginning of the eleventh century two brothers, Herred and Hacket, possessed considerable
allodial estates in Poperinghe,
but were persecuted by the Count of Guines and the Count of Boulogne, powerful neighbors, each of whom wanted to obtain feudal suzerainty
over these lands. The elder Herred,
in order to put an end to these vexations, surrendered his estates to the
Bishop of Terouanne and
received them back as a hereditary fief (perpetuum et hereditarium recepit in feodum), while the junior
brother effected a similar release of his part of the estates to the Count of
Boulogne.
The dangers of keeping
outside the feudal nexus were self-evident : in a time of fierce struggles for
bare existence it was necessary for everyone to look about for support, and the
protection of the central authority in the State was, even at its best, not
sufficient to provide for the needs of individuals. Even in England, where the
Conquest had given rise to a royal power possessed of very real authority, and
the king’s peace was by no means a mere word, the maintenance afforded by
powerful lords was an important factor in obtaining security.
In any case the feudal nexus
originated by such conditions involved reciprocity. The vassal expected gifts
and at least efficient protection, and sometimes the duty of the suzerain in
this respect is insisted on in as many words; as the French jurist Beaumanoir has it, “the lord is quite as much bound to be
faithful to his man as the latter is bound in regard to the lord” (Coutumes de Beauvaisis, 58). If the tenant
thought that he was not treated properly, feudal theory allowed him to sever
the connection. He might leave the estate (déguerpissement) without any further claim on the
part of the lord, but according to French notions he might even do more, namely
disavow the subjection to the lord while retaining the estate (désaveu). The Assizes of
Jerusalem are careful to state the cases of denial of right, in which a vassal
may rightfully renounce his obligations in regard to his immediate lord with the
natural consequence that henceforth such duties are transferred to the overlord
of the one at fault (Assises de Jerusalem, ‘gager le fief’). This
implied a proof on his part that the lord had not fulfilled his part of the
agreement. Though as a matter of fact such a désaveu led more often to war than to a
judicial process, it was derived from a juridical conception, and expressed the
view that the man, vassal or tenant, had definite rights as against his lord.
Some of the famous assertions of feudal independence on the part of barons
opposed to royal lords are based on this very doctrine of désaveu for breach
of agreement. Thus the barons of Aragon swore to their king that they would
obey and serve him if he maintained the rights, customs and laws of the kingdom,
and if not, not. The peers of the Kings of Jerusalem, according to the Assizes,
might in case of infringement of their rights lawfully refuse allegiance and
offer resistance. The clause of the Great Charter stipulating that a committee
of twenty-five barons should watch King John’s actions, and in case of his
breaking his solemn pledges should make war on him and call on all his subjects
to do the same, proceeds from the same fundamental assumption. This view was
readily extended from the notion of a breach of agreement between the lord and
his tenants to a conception of infringement of laws in general. In this way the
feudal view could be made a starting-point for the development of a
constitutional doctrine. We may notice this in the case of Bracton.
In his treatise on the laws of England, written at the time of Simon de
Montfort’s supremacy, the English judge, instead of urging with the Roman
jurists and with his predecessor Glanvill that
the sovereign’s will has the force of law, states that kings are not above the
law, although they have no single human superior (f. 5 v.) and that they ought
to be restrained by their peers from breaking the law (f. 34).
The other side of the medal
is presented by the duties of vassals in regard to the lord. Close analysis
shows that these duties proceed from different sources. There is to begin with
a general obligation of fealty, faithful obedience (fidelitas) which is owed by all subjects of the
lord without distinction of rank, the rustic subjects (villani) being especially concerned. This
obligation evidently had its roots in the relation between sovereign and
subject, and in so far represented rather the gradual decay of sovereign power
than the purely contractual side of feudalism; but in so much as fealty became
a relation between private lords and their subjects, it was related to the
feudal nexus and combined in various ways with the kindred notions of homage
and investiture. Homage again, which is distinctly contractual, arises
essentially from a contract of service. It proceeds directly from the bond
created by free agreement between a leader and a follower, the lord (hlaford) and his man. But this
contract of service gradually assumed a peculiar form: the personal duties of
the servant-retainer are asserted only occasionally, e.g. at a coronation
ceremony, when great feudatories are made to present dishes and cups, to lead
horses, to superintend the arrangements of the bedroom. As a rule, the central
duty of the vassal comes to be his military service, regulated according to a
certain number of days, generally forty, or a scutage payment
in redemption of the latter. Knight service of this kind shades off almost
imperceptibly into so-called military serjeanties,
that is, services of archers, of garrison soldiers, etc.
Ministeriales; dominium
These again are not easily
divided from petty serjeanties, in which
the menial services are still regarded as characteristic of the bond. In the
lists of serjeanties drawn up in the reign
of Edward I (published in the volumes of Feudal Aids and in the Testa de Nevill)
we find mentions of cooks, falconers, foresters, etc. In German feudal custom
the ministeriales correspond
to the servientes of
England and France, but there is a peculiar trait about their condition,
namely, that they are distinctly unfree in origin. Some of the greatest
warriors of German medieval history came from such unfree stock Marquard ot Anweiler, for instance, who received the March of
Ancona as a fief from Emperor Frederick II, was a ministerialist an
unfree retainer of the Emperor. As homage creates a relation between man and
man, it is not intrinsically bound up with landholding, and a good many of the
personal followers and servants of medieval magnates must certainly have lived
in the castles of their lords, receiving equipment and arms from them : they
saw in the good cheer of the court and in occasional gifts a reward for their
personal attendance. But such personal relations tended naturally to strike
root in land. If the retainer was at all useful and efficient he expected to be
remunerated by a permanent source of income, and such an outfit could only take
the shape of a grant of land. On the other hand, when a small landowner sought
protection from a magnate, he had generally to throw his tenement into the
balance and reassume it as a fief. Thus homage and investiture, although
historically and institutionally distinct, grow, as it were, together, and form
the normal foundation of feudal contract.
Besides the political coloring of this contract, it assumes a peculiar aspect
from the point of view of land law. It gives rise to a significant distinction
of two elements in the notion of ownership (dominium). Roman property
(dominium) was characterized during the best period by uncompromising unity. A
person having dominium over a thing, including an estate in land, had it alone
and excluded everyone else. Medieval lawyers, on the other hand, came to deal
with plots of land which had normally two owners, a superior and an inferior, one
having the direct ownership (dominium directum, dominium eminens), the other having the useful ownership,
the right to exploit the land (dominium utile). In England the splitting of the
notion of dominium was avoided by opposing the tenure in domain to the tenure
of service (tenere in dominio in servicio, see, e.g., Notebook of Bracton, case 1436), but the necessity for reckoning
with two kinds of right in respect of every holding contributed indirectly to
weaken the notion of absolute property in land. Contentions as to land were
made to turn principally on seisin, protected
possession, while the proof of title, which had played an important part in
later Anglo-Saxon times, receded, as it were, into the background. Instead of
trying to ascertain who the person was who ought to exercise the absolute right
of ownership, English courts came to concern themselves with the practical
question which of the two litigants had relatively the better right (ius merum) in regard to an estate or tenement. From the
feudal point of view an estate held as a fief could be freely parceled out to under-tenants who would become the vassals
of the man holding directly of the lord, provided the obligations of that
intermediate tenant were not lessened by such a process. Indeed it was not
uncommon for tenants to pass on the onerous duties with which the tenement was
charged to these under-tenants, who in such a case were called upon to ‘defend’
the land in regard to the superior lord in order that the mesne (medius, middle) lord should be
able to enjoy his tenure in peace.
Subinfeudation; reliefs
Various complications arose
from such subinfeudation in connection with customary requirements, and it was
clearly in the interest of the overlords to restrict such parceling of fees as much as possible. The English Crown
cut short the practice by the statute Quia Emptores,
which provided that in future the creation of any new fief would involve not
subinfeudation but the recognition by the new tenant of immediate dependence on
the overlord : thus the grantee of a new fief was placed on the same level as
the grantor instead of being subordinated to him.
The incidents arising out of
the double claims to land were manifested in a striking manner in cases when
the personnel of the contracting parties was changed, more especially when in
consequence of the death of the tenant a new representative of the dominium
utile had to come in. While in the case of a Thronfall, as the Germans said, that is, of the
demise of the lord, homage and fealty had to be merely renewed, a Lehnfall, the demise of the
vassal, brought about a temporary resumption of the fief by the direct owner,
i.e. by the lord : as a rule he was bound to re-grant the fief to the right
heir, but such a reinvestiture was
accompanied by a relief, a more or less heavy payment.
The struggle of English
barons for reasonable reliefs called forth well-known stipulations of the
charters of Henry I and of John. In the case of so-called base holdings the
relief had its analogy in the heriot, the surrender to the lord of the best
horse or the best ox, and there can be no doubt that this due, which had grown
from the custom of surrendering the outfit provided by the lord to his
dependent, was originally used quite as much in military fiefs as in villein or socage tenements.
In feudal practice, however, the military heriot was absorbed by the relief,
while it kept its ground in regard to base tenure.
The resumption of tenancies
connected with ecclesiastical offices led, as is well known, to protracted struggles
as to rights of investiture between the Church and State. Even when reinvestiture was made
dependent on canonical elections, the fiscal interests of the secular power had
to be satisfied by the diversion of ecclesiastical revenues for a year or a similar
customary period for the benefit of the Crown or of other secular patrons.
There were other occasional rights connected with a breach of the continuity of
possession, which would not arise out of vacancies in ecclesiastical
institutions; such were wardship and
marriage, which accrued to the lords in cases when fiefs descended to minors or
to unmarried females. These eventualities gave rise to very lucrative rights,
and it is a matter of common knowledge to what extent such opportunities were
liable to be misused. The English Charters contained provisions against these
abuses, but even in their mitigated form these practices were likely to produce
much hardship. Special classes of misdeeds arose in connection with them: we
hear of judicial proceedings taken on account of ravishment (kidnapping) of
wards and of ravishment of heiresses in order to get the profits, even when the
corresponding right belonged to someone else or was contested. From such
exactions ecclesiastical tenements were free, and this alone would have
sufficed to make the passage of landed property into the hands of the churches
undesirable from the feudal point of view. No wonder powerful kings tried to
restrict the passage of estates into the ‘dead hand’ (manus mortua)
of the Church. This was among other things the aim of Edward I’s Statute
De religiosis.
Although these reassertions
of the dominium directum forcibly
showed that the proprietary rights of the lord were by no means a dead
letter, the useful domain was protected from wanton interruption by
clearly established customs. The beneficia,
which preceded fiefs in historical evolution, were assumed to be granted for
life, but when fiefs developed out of them they nearly always became
hereditary. The only exception of any importance is presented by the beneficia militaria of
French Navarre. As political subjection was regarded as a matter of contract,
the feudal nexus tended towards a disruption of sovereignty, and often led in
practice to the formation of numerous political bodies within the boundaries of
historical States. This was especially the case in France, Germany and Italy.
An authoritative jurist like Beaumanoir summarized
the position in the saying, “chaque baron est souverain dans sa baronie”; and the mottoes chosen
by some of the French magnates gave expression to an unmeasured feeling of
self-sufficiency. The Rohans of
Brittany boasted: “prince ne daigne, roi ne puis, Rohan je suis”. The seigneur of Coucy,
a barony which gave great trouble to the early Capetian kings, disguised his
pride by mock humility: “je ne suis ni comte, ni marquis,
je suis le sire
de Coucy”. In Germany
the dismemberment of sovereignty was finally recognized by express law in
Charles IV’s Golden Bull of 1356 in favor of the
seven Electors, but it had already been acknowledged in regard to princes in
general by Frederick II, and had been acted upon more or less all through the
eleventh and twelfth centuries in the course of the protracted feuds between
Frankish and Swabian Emperors, on the one hand, and their various vassals on
the other. When Frederick Barbarossa went down on his knees, according to
tradition, when imploring Henry the Lion of Saxony and Bavaria to stand by him
against the rebel Italians, it would have been difficult to say that the
Emperor was the sovereign and the duke a mere subject.
Private war and its remedies
A most important consequence
of this acknowledgment of sovereign rights on the part of vassals of the Crown
lay in the fact that the latter could resort to actual war, when asserting
claims or defending infringed interests. The endeavors,
which were made by the Church, by royal suzerains and by the barons themselves
to restrict and suppress private warfare, are in themselves characteristic of
what we should call the anarchy of the times. The end of the tenth century
witnessed many attempts to put an end to private wars in France. In consequence
of terrible epidemics and bad harvests, which were regarded as signs of divine
wrath and incitements to repentance, the magnates of central and northern
France met, agreed to renounce private war, and confirmed this resolve by
solemn oaths. Gerard, Bishop of Cambrai,
objected to this as political; he was much abused by the other members of the
congress for holding aloof, and yet, as the chronicler remarks, events proved
that he was right.
It soon became evident that
it was impossible to suppress the pernicious custom entirely. The Truce of God
made its appearance in completion of the Peace of God. The time from Thursday
night to Monday morning was considered a time of truce on account of the
memories of the Lord’s sufferings and resurrection. Churches and churchyards
were naturally considered as hallowed and therefore neutral territory. In the
South, olive-trees were declared to be exempt from destruction by reason of
their vital importance in the economy of the country. The movement for ‘truce’
attained material results under the guidance of the Church in the eleventh and
twelfth centuries, and it became even more effective in the thirteenth, when
political potentates took it up. Still, even St Louis did not insist on a
complete abandonment of the practice of private war by his vassals : he only
enforced from all those, who resorted to the last argument of war, submission
to certain rules as to its declaration, the beginning of hostilities, their
course and so on; the quarantaine le Roi was a code as to usage in private war.
To Germany some order was
brought by powerful leagues between princes and knights on the one hand, cities
on the other. Such leagues were offensive and defensive alliances, and
ultimately had recourse to force of arms in order to maintain their position.
But as all extensive armaments are apt to do, they prevented the danger and
disorder of petty collisions. It was only towards the end of the Middle Ages
that something like a peace of the Empire
was recognized and to a certain extent secured by the reforms of Maximilian's
age. In England the franchise or right of private war was suppressed at a very
early time. It did not tally with the social order inaugurated by the Norman
Conquest, and the king’s peace became one of the mainstays of early Common Law.
The only period when the real disruption of sovereignty through private war
seemed to prevail was the interregnum when Stephen of Boulogne and the
Plantagenets struggled for the Crown. But this lapse into anarchy was short,
and from the time when Henry II restored order, private war ceased to be
recognized as a legal outcome of disputes. Yet the conditions of military contract
remained the foundation of government, and this made it possible for opposition
to wrong to take the form of armed resistance. The revolt against John, the
barons’ war against Henry III, the risings of Mortimer and Bolingbroke, the
Wars of the Roses, have as their necessary background a society ruled by groups
of knights, who considered themselves not merely as subjects, but as peers of
the king.
One of the most important
consequences of the disruption of sovereignty lay in the alienation of rights
of jurisdiction by the central government. As early as the ninth and tenth
centuries we observe everywhere the growth of franchises and immunities which
break up the ordinary sub-divisions of countries in respect of the
administration of justice. The English shires and hundreds, the continental
counties and Grafschafien are
riddled with districts in which the place of the ordinary judges of the land is
taken by secular or ecclesiastical magnates or their representatives, among
whom the secular judges of ecclesiastical corporations, the advocati (avoués, Vogte), are the most
conspicuous. The Sac and Soc grants of
Anglo-Saxon kings, as well as the various privileges of immunity conferred by
Carolingian, Franconian and Saxon
monarchs, present different steps in the process of political dismemberment.
The central authorities merely strove to retain their hold on the most
important varieties of jurisdiction, especially judgments as to great crimes,
the Ungerichte, as
they were termed in Germany, for which a man may lose his head and his hand (Haupt und Hand), while jurisdiction in minor cases,
when a person would only be chastised in skin or hair (in Haut oder Haar), were left to local potentates. From similar
considerations early English kings tried as much as possible to retain in their
hand the great forfeitures. This led eventually to a classification of feudal
tribunals according to the amount of jurisdiction acquired by them, some
claiming high and some low justice (haute or basse justice). The proceedings of Quo Warranto instituted by Edward I after his victory
over the baronial opposition show a most exuberant growth of prescriptive
rights in regard to the use of gallows, pillory, tumbrel, etc. by English
noblemen and ecclesiastical magnates. The institution of the advocaria (avouerie, Vogtei), on the contrary, never
attained to much importance in England, while it flourished greatly in Germany,
France and Flanders. It sprang from the delegation of public power within the
territory of an ecclesiastical franchise to a layman, who thereby came to be a
kind of policemaster as
well as a judge. The ordinary judges, the counts and their subordinates were
forbidden to enter the enfranchised district. On the other hand the bishop or
abbot at the head of it abstained from the shedding of blood and did not meddle
with criminal justice or deal with cases of public coercion : he appointed an
advocate who had to arrest criminals, to conduct them before the proper courts,
to execute those found guilty, to assist the ecclesiastical lord in cases when
force had to be employed for the collection of rents or the taking of distress.
These powers ripened in the course of the feudal age to an independent
jurisdiction which greatly hampered the freedom of action of the ecclesiastical
lord and encroached on his interests. Besides, churches and monasteries often
availed themselves of the advocaria in
order to obtain protection from a powerful neighbor :
the surrender of certain rights and sources of income was the price paid for
support in those troubled times. No wonder that in the eleventh and twelfth
centuries the advocates often became local tyrants at whose hands their clients
had to suffer a great deal. This is how, for instance, the Cartulary of
St Mihiel in
Flanders describes the conduct of a certain Count Raynald, an advocate of the monastery in question :
“Count Raynald was
the first to commit robberies in our estates under the customary term of talliatae; he also put our men
into prison and forced them to give up their own by means of torture he
bequeathed this tyranny to his son, the present Raynald. The latter exceeded the malice of his
father to such an extent that our men cannot put up any longer with such
oppression and leave our estates. They are either unable or do not care to
acquit themselves of outstanding rents : he is the only person they are afraid
of”.
Counsel and aid
The conflicts between
ecclesiastical potentates and their secular advocates often led to regular
treaties, the so-called règlements d’avouerie. The Vogt of the
Abbey of Prüm is
forbidden to ‘clip’ (tondere clip
the hair as for convicts) or to flay anyone except those who are guilty of
murder, brigandage or battery, nor has he any part in the wergeld of a man
unless he has helped to capture and to judge him. In Echternach the Vogt is excluded from
participating in civil trials. In houses appertaining to the garden and the
cellar, the laundry and the kitchen of the monks, he is forbidden to hold any
pleas or to exact any services, except pro monomachia (trial by battle) et sanguinea percussura et scabinis constituendis (the
appointment of popular assessors of the tribunals). The long-standing rivalry
between ecclesiastical institutions and their advocates was ultimately composed
by the intervention of the Crown when the latter grew strong. If we turn to
consider the relations between the lord and his vassals, we shall naturally
find that they differ greatly from the relations established at the present
time between the sovereign and his subjects. In the case of the privileged
holders of fiefs, however small, the tie which united them with their suzerain
being one not of general subordination but of limited obligation, the view that
the general will has to prevail over the particular and can impose rules of
conduct upon it did not hold good. Noble vassals, ecclesiastics possessed of
fiefs, and townsmen as members of municipal corporate bodies were as regards
their lords bound to abstain from certain acts and to perform certain duties. A
systematic treatment of this kind of contractual relation may be found in a
letter of Bishop Fulbert of Chartres to the Duke of
Aquitaine (eleventh century). The duties which he enumerates are derived more
especially from the oath of fealty, which accompanied the homage ceremony and
was distinct from the fealty of the base and non-privileged population to be
mentioned later on.
The negative duties of the
faithful vassal are indicated by the following terms : incolume, tutum, honestum, utile,
facile, possibile.
The Benedictine editors of Fulbert’s work
have explained these expressions to mean that the vassal undertakes not to
assail his lord, not to repeal his secret, not to endanger the safety of his
castles, not to wrong him in his judicial power, honors and possessions or to put obstacles in his way which would render what he
undertakes difficult or impossible. On the positive side the vassal is bound to
give his lord advice and aid (consilium, auxilium). From the positive obligations of consilium and auxilium various concrete duties are derived. The
principal form of advice (consilium)
tendered to the lord by his men consists in their obligation to attend his
court. Every lord had a court of his own, but not every court of this kind was
competent to judge all cases. A feudal distinction has to be drawn in this
respect between cases arising from the feudal nexus and cases of delegated
public jurisdiction. These latter comprised chiefly criminal cases classified,
as already pointed out, under the heads of high and low justice. The privilege
of giving sentence in them and of exercising the fiscal exactions connected
with them accrued only to those among the feudal lords who had obtained the
corresponding franchises through express grant or by force. They were
called seigneurs justiciers in France.
The more numerous class of ordinary lords held courts if they had tenants of
fiefs, and vassals and villein subjects
under them. These feudal courts took cognizance of all processes as to land
distributed by the lord to his dependents, but also to a great extent as to
pleas concerning the persons of the vassals. The first group of pleas stands
out so clearly that there is no special necessity to dwell on its range. It
need only be noticed that the proceedings concerning unfree tenures were
substantially of the same kind as those affecting free or noble tenancies. A
dispute as to the possession of a villenagium followed
on the same lines as a trial in which a free tenement was the object in
dispute, although the latter was naturally much more complex. From the
technical point of view, in the first case the trial took place before the
peers of the contending parties, who as suitors of the court were its judges,
while in the second case the lord or his steward was the only judge and such
assessors as were called up had only advisory powers. But as a matter of fact
the verdicts of the court were regarded as the expression of legal custom in
the second case, and the reservation that the lord might override the customary
rules was due to his exceptional position, and not to the ordinary working of
manorial courts. A body of legal tradition and of conceptions of equity grew up
in the lower social stratum as well as in the upper. This is especially
noticeable in the case of English manorial courts, in the composition of which
free and unfree elements are generally intermixed in such a way that it is
difficult to distinguish between verdicts laid down by the free tenants and
those contributed by the villeins. The one
really important difference lay in the fact that the villeins had
to look for justice to the manorial court in all cases, not only tenurial, but also personal, such as cases of battery,
defamation, adultery and the like, while free men and specially men of noble
birth were either directly amenable to justice by the medium of the royal
tribunals or could, if they appeared before a feudal court, insist on a very
strict maintenance of their privileges in view of the supervision of royal
courts.
Appeal of judgment
In a sense the circle of
tenants constituting the peers’ court was a most complete expression of the principle
of equality as between allied sovereigns. The decision was formulated strictly
by the peers of the contending parties, and this led, in regard to criminal
accusations, to the famous doctrine of the Great Charter:
“nullus liberhomo capiatur vel imprisonetur nisi
per judicium parium suorum vel per legem terrae” (sect. 39).
The decision of a court of
peers was final. An appeal was impossible from the feudal point of view,
because it would have meant a revision of the judgment by higher authority, and
feudal litigants submitted not to higher authority but to a convention in which
they had taken part. There were, however, two cases in which a vassal might
seek redress from a source of law superior to the court of peers presided over
by his suzerain. If justice was denied to him by this tribunal he could ask the
overlord, that is, the suzerain of his immediate lord, to see that justice
should be done. This was, however, no appeal as to law or facts, but only an
attempt to set the machinery of feudal jurisdiction in motion. The second
eventuality occurred when one of the parties to a suit actually contested the
justice of a particular decision or sentence. He could in French feudal law
attaint or falsify the verdict by pronouncing the formula, “je vous appelle de faux jugement”. This meant that he challenged the
fairness and honor of the judges, and the result was
single combat between the protesting party and one or several of the judges,
not a satisfactory solution of the difficulties from our point of view, nor,
probably, from that of many judges concerned. There were devices which rendered
such attaint hazardous in some cases : the members of the tribunal could
pronounce the decision in corpore, and in this
case the option for the dissatisfied party was to fight them all. In any case
this mode of appeal was directed towards the revision of the judgment by God
rather than by man, and at bottom did not subvert the principle that a man
ought to be judged by his peers and by his peers only. It is hardly necessary
to add that the falsifying of judgments has been described here in conformity
to strict rules of feudal theory. In practice all sorts of compromises took
place. In England, for example, the revision of judgments by higher courts was
brought about at a very early stage by the intervention of the king’s court,
though not without opposition from the barons. An instructive case occurred,
for example, in the reign of William the Conqueror. In a trial as to land
between Bishop Gundulf of
Rochester and Picot, the Sheriff of Cambridgeshire,
the county pronounced in favor of the latter, but
through the intervention of Odo of Bayeux twelve representatives of the shire
were called up to confirm the verdict by oath in the king’s court, and
ultimately, after a declaration by a monk who had been steward of the estate in
question, the unlucky doomsmen were driven
either to go through the ordeal of red-hot iron or to recant. The indirect way
in which the prejudiced intervention of the higher powers took effect in
this case is characteristic of the traditional difficulties which stood in
the way of downright revision. As on many other occasions; there are threads
connecting feudal theory with recent or actual practice, and we may not
unreasonably see in the doctrine as to the finality of jury verdicts a
modernized offshoot of the older doctrine of the judgment by peers. Of course
the differentiation between questions of fact and questions of law has made it
possible to concede to juries the highly privileged position which they
generally enjoy, but the germ of the corresponding rules is historically
connected with the immunity from outside influence which formed one of the most
characteristic traits of the feudal judgment by peers.
Similar phenomena meet our
eye when we come to consider the processes of legislation obtaining in the
feudal world. It is evident in theory that a baron, being a sovereign, could
not be subjected to any will but his own, and that therefore such common
arrangements as had to be made in medieval society had to be effected on the
same lines as modern international conventions. And indeed we find this idea at
the root of the feudal doctrine of legislation; in the custom of Touraine-Anjou
it was expressed in the following way : “The baron has all manner of justice in
his territory, and the king cannot proclaim his command in the land of the
baron without the latter’s consent; nor can the baron proclaim his command in
the land of his tenant without the consent of the tenant”.
In consequence of this general
principle, all feudal legislation ranging outside the immediate demesne of the
single baron takes the shape of a stabilimentum (établissement) or of an assize
enacted in the court of a superior lord with the express or implied consent of
his vassals. An ordinance of the Viscount of Thouars (AD 1099), for example, instituting a
certain annual charge to be paid by the tenants, refers at the close to “the
authority and will of the barons of my land” (quoted by Luchaire, Manuel des
Institution Françaises,
p. 253). The same notion reappears in ordinances made by much greater
potentates, such as the dukes of Normandy, e.g. by William the Conqueror, in
1064 (on public peace), by Counts of Flanders (Baldwin of Constantinople, in
1199, on usury), by Dukes of Brittany (in 1185, on succession to fiefs), even
by kings of France, and kings of England; Henry II’s Assize of the Forest, for
instance begins in the following manner : “This is the assize of the Lord King
Henry, the son of Maud, in England, about forest and hunting, by the advice and
consent (per consilium et assensum) of the
archbishops, bishops, barons, earls (comitum)
and noblemen of England at Woodstock”. Theoretically, the individual consent of
each member of the gathering to any decision was needed if it were to bind him,
but historically, the legislative assemblies were not merely the outcome of
feudal meetings, they were also survivals of more ancient popular assemblies,
while, as a matter of practice, the authority of the superior lord and the influence
of leading magnates asserted themselves in a much greater degree than would
have been allowed from a purely individual point of view. It thus depended very
much on circumstances whether centripetal or centrifugal tendencies got the
upper hand. The majority principle had not been evolved either, at least during
the eleventh, twelfth and thirteenth centuries. As the French historian Luchaire has expressed it,
voices were rather weighed than counted. But the idea of a convention made
itself felt in a very definite manner, and this point must be noticed as very
important in view of subsequent development. The early doctrine of medieval
estates is clearly connected with these feudal views on the side both of
legislation and taxation. The view that the nation is not bound to pay a tax to
the imposition of which it has not consented through its representatives (the
constitutional rule on which the development of Parliament depended later on)
certainly has its roots in the feudal maxim that no baron was bound by ordinances
in the ‘establishment’ of which he had not taken a part. It is also not alien
to our purpose to notice that the distinction between greater and smaller
barons suggested by the far-reaching differences, in regard to the
appropriation of public power, afforded a germ for the subsequent rise of
aristocratic ‘ Second Chambers’. The House of Lords, as a court, is a house of
peers, and it is not only in England that the prominence of the magnates
secured for them a special personal standing in legislative organization: a
curious parallel, all the more instructive because it is supplied by a
microscopic state, is presented by the history of Béarn in the Pyrenees. In that vicomté, an aristocratic council
of twelve hereditary jurati drawn
from the most powerful houses of local nobility, appears as the cour majour and acts as a standing committee of the
full court (cour plénière). It had to settle
disputes between the viscounts and their vassals and in general to control the
current administration of law.
A survey of medieval society
from the one point of view of contractual relations would, however, be
incomplete, one-sided and artificial. In order to be correct it ought to be
matched by an examination of the constituent elements combining to form the
feudal organization. Such an examination would have to take each feudal unit
singly and to describe the rule of the lord over his subjects as well as the
work of these subjects. The most characteristic type of such a feudal unit is
certainly the English manor, and I should like to turn now to a study of it
which will afford a key to the understanding of similar phenomena in other
countries of Western Europe. The manor is a necessary outcome of so-called
natural husbandry, providing for the requirements of life by work carried out
on the spot, without much exchanging and buying. It is the connecting link in
the social life of classes, some of which are primarily occupied with the rough
work of feeding, clothing and housing society, while others specialize in
defending it and providing for its secular and spiritual government. It
presents the lowest and most efficient unit of medieval organization, and local
justice, administration and police are all more or less dependent on its
arrangements. Let us look at the different elements of which this historical
group is composed.
The village community
First of all there is the
economic element. The manor afforded the most convenient, and even the
necessary, arrangements of work and profit in those times. It would be quite
wrong to assume that the interests and rights of the many were simply
sacrificed to the interests and rights of a few rulers, that the manor was
nothing but an estate, cultivated and exploited for the sake of the lord and
managed at discretion by his will and the will of his servants. On the
contrary, one of the best established facts in the economic life of the manor
was its double mechanism, if one may say so. It consisted, as a rule, of a
village community with wide though peculiar self-government and of a manorial
administration superimposed on it, influencing and modifying the life of the
community but not creating it. This double aim and double mechanism of the
manor must be noticed at the outset as a very characteristic feature; it places
the manor in a sharp contrast both to the plantations of slaves of the ancient
world and to the commercial husbandry of a modern estate struggling for profit
as best it may.
Manorial husbandry was all
along striving towards two intimately connected aims, providing the villagers
with means of existence and providing the lord with profits. Hence a dual
machinery to attain these aims, both a village community and the lord’s
demesne.
The village community lay at
the basis of the whole. It gave rise to a very peculiar system of holding and
using land, not to be confused either with the case of the tribal community in
which rights are graduated according to the pedigree of a person, or with that
of the communalism of the Russian mir or
of some Hindu settlements, in which land is allotted and redivided according to the requirements and the
economic strength of the settlers. The peculiar bent of the English rural
community would perhaps be best indicated by the expression ‘shareholding
arrangement’ or ‘community of shareholders’. Each of the households settled in
the village had a fixed and constant share, or maybe half a share, or a
quarter, or the eighth part of a share assigned to it. It stood in scot and in
lot with the village as a hide or two virgates or
one virgate or a bovate, according to
the size of the share. By the standard of this hereditary share all rights and
duties were apportioned. By the side of the shareholders there generally lived
in the village smaller tenants (cottagers, crofters) but they were merely an
adjunct to the main body of the tenantry and
may be left out of reckoning in our general survey.
The system of communal
shareholding was very strikingly illustrated by the treatment of waste and
pasture in the medieval village. It was not divided among the tenants, and,
though later in legal theory it belonged to the lord, it was everywhere
considered by custom as a ‘common’ for the use of the villagers. In most cases
it had to be stinted to some extent : rules were formulated as to the species
and number of beasts to be sent to pasture, as to seasons, and as to
precautions against abuses; and these rules can generally be traced to the main
principle, that every household has to use the common according to the size of
its share, so that, for instance, a virgater had the right to send two cows
and eight sheep to the pasture, while the owner of a bovate could
only send one cow and four sheep, and so on. The use of wood for building
purposes, of hedges for fuel, of turf, and other profits drawn from the common
and undivided fund of the village, were regulated by rules or by-laws of the
same kind. In regard to meadows, which were scarce and highly valued, the
communalism of the village found a suitable expression in the division of these
meadows into a certain number of strips according to the number of households
taking part in the community : these strips were then allotted to one after the
other of the households in a customary order or by casting lots. The arable did
not change hands in the same way. As a rule, the strips of the arable were
owned by each household in hereditary succession, each generation entering into
the rights of the preceding generation in this respect. But, even in the case
of the arable, there were many facts to show that it was considered dependent
on the community, though held to a certain extent in severalty by the
households. To begin with, the holding in severalty existed on the land only
for one part of the year. The tenant had a particular right to it while it was
under crop, that is, when it had been ploughed up and sown, and while the
harvest had not yet removed the proceeds of the individual labor and care which the tiller had bestowed upon it. As most fields were cultivated
in medieval England on the three-field or on the two-field system, the
households of shareowners obtained private rights over their arable strips
while winter corn or spring corn grew on the soil, and these separate rights
were marked off by narrow lines of turf between the strips, called balks, while
the whole of the sown field was protected from the inroads of cattle by a
temporary hedge. But after harvest had been gathered the hedges fell, and the
whole field returned to the condition of waste to be used for pasture as a
common : a condition which took up the whole of every third year in a
three-field and the whole of every second year in a two-field husbandry,
besides a considerable part of the years when the field received seed. Private
occupation of the strips emerged in this way from time to time from the open
common field, an arrangement which not only kept up the principle that the
arable was, after all, the property of the village as a whole, but had direct
practical consequences in hampering private industry and the use of private capital
in cultivation : it rendered, for instance, manuring a
very complicated and rather exceptional process. Nor is this all : the
householder did not only cease to cultivate his plot as soon as harvest was
over, but he had, even before then, to conform in the plan and methods of
cultivation to the customs and arrangements of his neighbors.
The arable of his holding was generally composed of a certain number of strips
in proportion to the importance of his share, and these strips lay intermixed
with the strips of other villagers so that everyone came to own patches of
land, acres and half-acres in all the ‘shots and furlongs of the village’, as
the fields were called, and had to wander about in all directions to look after
his own. Such an arrangement would be the height of absurdity in any state of
society where individual ownership prevails, and this point by itself would be
sufficient to show that what was meant was not a division of claims according
to the simple rules of private ownership, so familiar to us, but a communal
cultivation in which the arable was divided between the shareholders with as
much proportionate fairness as possible. In keeping with this principle, the
plan of cultivation, the reclaiming of land, the sequence of seasons for its use
for wheat, barley, oats, peas, the time of its lying fallow, for setting up of
hedges and their removal, the rules as to sending cattle on to the stubble, and
the like, were worked out and put in practice, not by the industry of every
single householder, but by the decision of the village as a whole. We may even
discover traces of re-divisions, by which the shares of the householders were
partitioned anew according to the standard of proportionate importance, though
such instances are very exceptional and mostly connected with cases where some
confusion had occurred to break up the proper relations of the holdings. If we
look at the open-field system as a whole, we must insist upon the fact that the
key to its arrangement lies in the principle of shareholding, every household
being admitted to a certain proportion of rights according to its share in the
community, and being held to corresponding duties.
The village community has, as
a rule, a demesne farm superimposed on it, and the connection between the two
is very close and intimate. To begin with, the lord's demesne farm draws rents
in money and in kind from the plots of the tenants, and it serves as a
counting-house for the discharge of these rents. By the side of the
counting-house stand barns and stores, where the multifarious proceeds of
natural husbandry are gathered as they come in from the holdings. In some
manors the dues are arranged to form a complete outfit for the consumption of
the lord’s household, a farm of one night, of a week, of a fortnight, as the
case may be. The manors of the Abbey of Ramsey were bound to render as a
fortnight's farm 12 quarters of flour, 2000 loaves of bread, 24 gallons of
beer, 48 gallons of malt, 2 sesters of
honey, 10 flitches of bacon, 10 rounds of cheese, 10 very best sucking pigs, 14
lambs, 14 geese, 120 chickens, 2000 eggs, 2 tubs of butter, 24 gallons of audit
ale. In Lent the bacon and the cheese were struck off and money paid in their
stead.
By the help of these
accumulated stores, and of funds drawn from money rents and of small leases,
the lord keeps a number of servants, and hires some laborers for the
cultivation of the home farm, of the orchard; and the arable set apart for it,
as well as for looking after the buildings, the implements, etc. But the
peculiar feature of the manorial arrangement consists in the fact that the
demesne farm does not live independently of the village community adjoined to
it, does not merely draw profits from it in the way of rents, but actually gets
its labor from this village community and thereby
builds up its husbandry.
The most important of these
services is the week work performed by the peasantry. Every virgater or holder of
a bovate has to send a laborer to do work on the lord’s farm for about half the number of days in the week.
Three days is indeed the most common standard for service of this kind, though
four or even five occur sometimes, as well as two. It must be borne in mind in
the case of heavy charges, such as four or five days’ week work, that only one laborer from the whole holding is meant, while generally
there were several men living on every holding; otherwise the service of five
days would be impossible to perform. In the course of these three days, or
whatever the number was, many requirements of the demesne had to be met. The
principal of these was ploughing the fields belonging to the lord, and for such
ploughing the peasant had not only to appear personally as a laborer, but to bring his oxen and plough or rather to join
with his oxen and plough in the work imposed on the village : the heavy plough
with a team of eight oxen had usually to be made up by several peasants
contributing their beasts and implements towards its composition. In the same
way the villagers had to go through the work of harrowing with their harrows,
and of carrying the harvest in their wains and
carts.
Carrying duties, in carts and
on horseback, were also apportioned according to the time they took as a part
of the week work. Then came innumerable varieties of manual work for the
erection and keeping up of hedges, the preservation of dykes, canals, and
ditches, the threshing and garnering of corn, the tending and shearing of sheep
and so forth. All this hand-work was reckoned according to customary standards
as day work and week work. But alongside of all these services into which the
regular week work of the peasantry was distributed stood some additional
duties. The ploughing for the lord, for instance, was not only imposed in the
shape of a certain number of days in the week, but also took the shape of a
certain number of acres which the village had to plough and to sow for the lord
irrespective of the amount of time it took to do so. This was sometimes
termed gafolearth.
Then again exceedingly burdensome services were required, in the seasons when
farming processes are, as it were, at their height, at times of mowing and
reaping when every day is of special value and the working power of the
farm-hands is strained to the utmost. At that time it was the custom to call up
the whole able-bodied population of the manor, with the exception of the
housewives, for two, three or more days of mowing and reaping on the lord's
fields. To these boonworks the
peasantry was asked or invited by special summons, and their value was so far
appreciated that the villagers were usually treated to meals in cases where
they were again and again called off from their own fields to the demesne. The
liberality of the lord actually went so far in exceptionally hard straits, as
to serve some ale to the laborers to keep them in good humor.
In this way the demesne farm throve as a kind of huge parasitical growth by
drawing on the strength of the tenantry.
The villeins
Let us now turn to the second
constitutive element of the manor, to what we have called its social aspect in
distinction to the economic and to the political aspects. From the social point
of view the manor is a combination of classes, and the three main classes are
to be found on its soil : the villeins, or as
they are sometimes called the customary tenants, the freeholders or free
tenants, and the officials and servants of the lord.
The villeins are
in the majority. They come from people whose position was by no means uniform.
Some of them are the offspring of slaves, some of free men who have lapsed into
serfdom through crime or inability to provide the means of existence. Some
claim to descend from the ceorls of Saxon
times, a class of free peasants who were gradually crushed down to rural
servitude. Be that as it may, the distinctive features of villeinage are derived from all its original sources
and are blended to form a condition which is neither slavery nor self-incurred
serfdom nor the subjection of free peasants to their rulers. Three main traits
seem especially characteristic of manorial villeinage:
the performance of rural services, the inability to claim and defend civil
rights against the lord, and the recognition of villeins as
free men in all matters concerning the political and criminal law of the realm.
Each of these traits deserves some special notice.
The villein is
primarily a man obliged to perform rural work for his lord. Every person in the
medieval social scheme is bound to perform some kind of work, every one holds
by some kind of service or appears as a follower of one who holds by some
service. The Church holds some of her lands in return for her obligation to
pray and to minister to spiritual needs. The knights and Serjeants hold theirs by military service of
different kinds. The burgesses and socagers hold
in the main by paying rents, by rent service. The villein has
to perform agricultural services to his lord. Some such agricultural services
may be linked to the tenure of other classes, to the tenure of socagers, burgesses, and even military tenants, but the
characteristic week work was primarily imposed on the villeins,
and though they sometimes succeeded in getting rid of it by commuting it for
money payments, these modifications of their status were considered as
secondary and exceptional, and generally some traces of the original
obligations of agricultural service were left : even privileged villeins had to serve their lord as reeves or rural
stewards, had to send their sheep to the lord’s fold, had to appear at the
bidding of manorial officers to perform one or the other kind of work in the
field. The villein was emphatically a man
who held by the fork and the flail.
In the early days of
feudalism agricultural service must have decided the fate of many people who
had good claims to rank as free. In a rough way the really important
distinction was this : on one side stood people who were bound to feed the rest
and were therefore bound to the glebe, on the other those who were free to go
wherever they pleased, provided they performed their military or ecclesiastical
duties, and paid their rents. But when once the main social cleavage had taken
place, the lawyers had to face a vast number of personal claims and disputes,
and they gradually worked out a principle which itself became a basis for
social distinctions, namely that the villein,
the peasant holding by rural work, had no civil claims against his lord. It was
convenient to assume that everything a villein possessed
was derived from a grant of his lord and liable to be resumed by him, and
though this may by no means be true in point of historical fact, it became as
good as true because the king’s courts declined to examine and decide civil
suits of villeins against their
lord. Villeins were left unprotected, and
this lack of protection gave birth to a series of customary exactions quite
apart from the many instances when a lord simply ill-treated the peasants.
A villein had to pay a fine on the
marriage of his daughter because she was considered the property of the lord,
and this fine was materially increased when she married out of the lordship, as
the lord lost his bond-woman and her offspring by such a marriage. On the death
of a villein his heir could not enter his
inheritance without surrendering a valuable horse or ox in recognition of the
claims of the lord to the agricultural outfit of the holding.
As a matter of fact the civil
disability of villeins did not amount to a
general insecurity of their rights of possession. On the contrary, the custom
of the manor was elaborately constant and provided for most contingencies of
rural life with as much accuracy and nicety of distinction as the law
administered in the royal courts. But all these provisions were merely
customary rules drawn from facts; they were not binding on the lord, and in one
very important respect, the amount and kind of work to be exacted from the
peasant, changes and increases occasionally occurred. There was one class of
the English peasantry which enjoyed a much better condition, namely the villeins on the so-called ancient demesne of the
Crown. In manors which had belonged to the kings before the Conquest and had
been granted to subjects after the Conquest, the lords had no right to oust the
villagers from their holdings and to increase their services at pleasure, but
were bound to follow the customs which held good at the time of the transfer of
the estates from the Crown. In such manors a recourse to the rural courts was
admitted and the peasants were treated as free people in regard to their
tenements and services; their tenure became a species of lease or contract,
though burdened with base services. This valuable privilege only emphasized
with greater sharpness the rightless condition
of the rest of the peasantry.
This rightlessness was, however, restricted to the
relations of the villeins with their lord.
In regard to all third persons and in regard to the requirements of the State
they were considered to be free. This is the third marked feature of their
condition. Let us remember that the slave of Roman and Saxon times was a thing,
an animal at best, that he was supposed to act merely on behalf of his master,
that if he committed a theft or slew somebody his master was held responsible
for his crime, and that he was not admitted as a warrior to the host and did
not pay any taxes to grasping fiscal authorities, though he was estimated at
his worth and more than his worth when his master had to pay. All these traits
of slavery gradually disappeared when slaves and ceorls were
blended in the mould of villeinage. The villein was
recognized as having a soul and a will of his own not only in the eyes of the
Christian Church but in those of the feudal State. He could enter into
agreements, and acquire property in spite of the fact that some authoritative
lawyers maintained that he could acquire nothing for himself and that all he
had belonged to his lord. He was set in the stocks or hanged for crimes, and
the lord had to be content with the loss of his man, as he had not to pay for
his felonies. Villeins were grouped
in frithborgs or tithings of frankpledge in order that the peace of
the realm and its police might be better enforced. They were not merely taxed
by their lords and through their lords, but also had to pay hidage and geld from their own land and fifteenths
and twentieths from their own chattels. Altogether the government looked upon
them as its direct subjects and did not fail to impose duties on them, though
it declined to protect their customary rights against the lord.
The celebrated enactments of
Magna Charta as to personal security and rights of property applied primarily
to free men and to free tenements and of such there were a good many in the
manor. Indeed a manor was deemed incomplete without them. Besides the knights
and squires or Serjeants who held of the
lord by military service, there were numerous tenants who stood to him in a
relation of definite agreement, paying certain fixed rents or performing
certain specified services which, however burdensome, did not amount to the
general obligation of rural labor incumbent on
the villeins. Many were the tenants, who,
without appealing to a charter or a specified agreement to prove their
contractual relation to the lord, held their tenements from father to son as if
there were a specific agreement between them and the lord, performing certain
services and paying certain rents ; and this class was the most important of
all. These were the freeholders properly so termed or, as they were called in many
ancient manors, the sokemen. Without going into
the question of their origin and history, we must emphatically lay down the
principle of their tenure in feudal society : it was tenure by contract and
therefore free. Such was its essence, although in many, perhaps in most cases,
the formation of the contract was hidden by lapse of time unto which memory
does not run, and indeed hardly amounted to more than a legal presumption. The
clear distinction, drawn by the Courts between tenants in a relation of
contract with their lord and tenants in a relation of customary subjection,
divided sharply the classes of freeholders and villeins and molded all the details of their personal position. It
was not always easy to make out in particular cases to which of the two great
subdivisions a person and a holding belonged, and, as a matter of history, the
process of pressing the people into the hard and fast lines of this
classification was achieved by disregarding previous and more organic
arrangements, but undoubtedly this distinction created a mould, which not only worked powerfully to bring some
order into feudal society, but set a definite aim before the very class which
was depressed by it; to obtain freedom the villeins must
aspire to contractual relations with their lords.
Freeholders
We are now concerned with the
period when these aspirations were only more or less indefinite ferments of
social progress, and the legal distinction still acted as a firm rule. The
freeholders sought and obtained protection for their rights in the royal courts
and thereby not only acquired a privileged position in regard to holdings, dues
and services, but in a sense, obtained an entirely different footing from
the villein and were able to step out of
the manorial arrangement, to seek their law outside it. This was undoubtedly
the case, and the countless records of law suits between lords and tenants tell
us of all the possibilities which such a position opened to the freeholders.
But it is necessary to realize the other side of the matter, which we may be
apt to disregard if we lay too much stress on the legal standing of freeholders
in the King's Courts. In all that touched the life and arrangements of the
village community underlying the manor, the freeholders were in scot and in lot
with the township and therefore on an equal footing with the villeins. In speaking of the management of open field and
waste, of the distribution of arable and meadows, of the practices of enclosure
and pasture, etc., we did not make any difference between villeins and freeholders, indeed we have not even
mentioned the terms. We have spoken of tenants, of members of the community, of
shareholders, and now that we have learnt to fathom the deep legal chasm
between the two sections of the tenantry, we
still must insist on the fact that both sections were at one in regard to all
the rights and duties derived from their agrarian association, appertaining to
them as tillers of the soil and as husbands of their homes. Both sections
joined to frame the by-laws and to declare the customs which ruled the life of
the village and its intricate economic practices. And the freeholders had not
only to take part in the management of the community but, of course, to conform
to its decisions. They were not free in the sense of being able to use their
plots as they liked, to manage their arable and pasture in severalty, to keep
up a separate and independent husbandry. If they transgressed against the rules
laid down by the community, they were liable to pay fines, to get their cattle
impounded, to have their property distrained upon. Of course, the processes of
customary law were greatly hampered and even modified by the fact that the
freeholders had access to the royal courts, and so could challenge the verdicts
of the manorial jurisdiction and the decisions of the township in the royal
courts. And undoubtedly the firm footing obtained by freeholders in this
respect enabled them on many occasions to thwart the petty jurisdiction of
their neighbors, and to set up claims which were not
in keeping with a subjection to by-laws made by the manorial community. But
this clashing of definitions and attributes, though unavoidable in view of the
ambiguous position of freeholders, must not prevent us from recognizing the
second principle of their condition as well as the first; they were not merely
tenants by contract but also members of a village community and subjected to
its by-laws.
After what has been said of
the position of the tenants, we need not dwell very long on the standing of the
lord and of his immediate helpers. The lord was a monarch in the manor, but a
monarch fettered by a customary constitution and by contractual rights. He was
often strong enough to break through these customs and agreements, to act in an
arbitrary way, to indulge in cruelty and violence. But in the great majority of
cases feelings and caprice gave way to reasonable considerations. A reasonable
lord could not afford to disregard the standards of fairness and justice which
were set up by immemorial custom, and a knowledge of the actual conditions of
life. A mean line had to be struck between the claims of the rulers and the
interests of the subjects, and along this mean line by-laws were framed and
customs grew up which protected the tenantry even
though it was forsaken by the king’s judges. This unwritten constitution was
safe- guarded not only by the apprehension that its infringement might scatter
the rustic population on whose labor the well-being
of the lord and his retainers after all depended, but also by the necessity of
keeping within bounds the power of the manorial staff of which the lord had to
avail himself. This staff comprised the stewards and seneschals who had to act
as overseers of the whole, to preside in the manorial courts, to keep accounts,
to represent the lord on all occasions; the reeves who, though chosen by the
villagers, acted as a kind of middlemen between them and the lord and had to
take the lead in the organization of all the rural services; the beadles
and radknights or radmen who had to
serve summonses and to carry orders; the various warders, such as the hayward, who had to superintend hedges, the woodward for pastures and
wood, the sower and the thresher; the graves of moors and dykes who had to look
after canals, ditches and drainage; the ploughmen and herdsmen, employed for
the use of the domanial plough-teams and
herds. All these ministri had
to be kept in check by a well- advised landlord, and one of the most efficient
checks on them was provided by the formation of manorial custom. It was in the
interest of the lord himself to strengthen the customary order which prevented
grasping stewards and Serjeants from
ruining the peasantry by extortions and arbitrary rule. This led to the great
enrolments of custom as to holdings and services, of which many have come down
to us from the twelfth, thirteenth and fourteenth centuries; they were a
safeguard for the interests both of the tenants and of the lord.
Local administration
The complex machinery of the
manor as the centre of economic affairs
and of social relations demanded by itself a suitable organization. But besides
this the manor was the local centre for
purposes of police and justice; it had to enforce the king’s commands and the
law of the realm in its locality. It would be more correct to say that the
manor and the village community or township underlying it were regarded as
local centers of justice and police, because in these
political matters the double aspect of the manor, the fact of its being
composed of an upper and a lower half, came quite as plainly to the fore as in
its economic working. Indeed, for purposes of justice, taxation, supervision of
vagabonds, catching and watching thieves, keeping in order roads, and the like,
the government did not recognize as the direct local unit the manor, but
the vill, the
village community or town, as the old English term went. The vill had to look
after the formation of frankpledge, to keep ward, to watch over prisoners and
to conduct them to gaol, to make presentments
to justices and to appear at the sheriff's turn. This fact is a momentous piece
of historical evidence as to the growth of manorial jurisdiction, but, apart
from that, it has to be noticed as a feature of the actual administration of
justice and police during the feudal period. It may be said that when the
central power appealed directly to the population either for help or for
responsibility, it did so through the medium not of the manors, but of the
ancient towns or townships merged in them.
But there were many affairs
delegated to the care of the manor, in which the central power intervened only
indirectly. There was the whole domain of petty jurisdiction over villeins, as subjects of the lord, there were the
numberless cases arising from agrarian transgressions and disputes, there were
disputes between tenants of the same lord in regard to land held from him,
there were the franchises, that is, the powers surrendered by special grants of
the government or by immemorial encroachment of the lords in regard to tolls,
market rights, the assize of bread and ale and other matters of commercial
police, to the trying of thieves, poachers, and the like. In all these respects
the manorial lord was called upon to act according to his standing arid
warranted privileges. But in no case could he act alone and by himself: he
acted in his court and through his court. Originally this court, the halimote, the hall meeting, as
we may translate the term, dealt with all sorts of affairs : it tried the cases
where villeins were concerned, transacted
the conveyancing business, enforced the jurisdiction of the franchises. Its
suitors were freeholders and villeins alike,
and if they did not always act jointly, we have at least no means of
distinguishing between the different parts they played. Gradually, however, a
differentiation took place, and three main types of courts came into being, the
Customary Court, the Court Baron and the Court Leet;
but we need not here concern ourselves with the technical distinctions involved
by this differentiation of courts.
All these details have a
simple and reasonable meaning when we consider them from the point of view of
an all-round arrangement of each locality for the settlement of all its
affairs, administrative, fiscal, jurisdictional, as well as economic and civil.
This confusing variety has to be explained by the fact that, notwithstanding
all strivings to make the manor complete and self-sufficient in this petty local
sphere, it could not cut itself off from the general fabric of the kingdom.
Through the channels which connected it with the central authorities came
disturbing elements; the privileges of free tenants, the control over the use
of franchises, the interference of royal courts and royal officers. All these
factors rendered manorial arrangements more complex and less compact than they
might otherwise have been; but, of course, these very elements insured its
further development towards more perfect forms of organization and prevented it
from degenerating into despotism or into caste.
The manor is peculiarly an
English institution, although it may serve to illustrate Western European
society in general. Feudalism, natural husbandry, the sway of the military class,
the crystallization of powers and rights in local centers,
are phenomena which took place all over Western Europe and which led in France,
in Germany, in Italy and Spain to similar though not identical results. It is
interesting to watch how in these bygone times and far-off customs some of the
historical traits which even now divide England from its neighbors are forming themselves at the very time when the close relationship between the
European countries is clearly visible. The disruption of the nation into local
organisms is more complete in France and in Germany than in England, which,
through the fact of the Norman Conquest and the early rise of Norman royalty
and Norman aristocracy, was welded into a national whole at a period when its
southern neighbors were nearly oblivious of national
union. Even so, the English manor was more systematically arranged and more
powerfully united than the French Seigneurie or the German Grundherrschaft. The
French baron ruled in an arbitrary manner over his serfs and was almost
powerless in regard to his free vassaux,
while the German Grundherr had
a most confusing complex of social groups to deal with, a complex more akin to
the classes of England which existed on the day when King Edward the Confessor
was ‘alive and dead’ than to the England of Henry II and Edward I. The social
distinction between the military class and the rural laboring class, the natural husbandry, which dispensed to a great extent with commercial
intercourse and money dealings, produced in all western countries the
subjection of villeins and the
super-imposition of a lord’s demesne on the holdings of the working-class. But
instead of assuming the form of a union between the lord's demesne and a firmly
organized village community, the central economy of the lord had to deal in
France with loose clusters of separate settlements, while in Germany the
communal element combined with the domanial in
all sorts of chance ways, which, though very advantageous in some cases, did
not develop without difficulty into a firmly established and generally
recognized body of rural custom.
In England things were
different. There can be hardly any doubt that through the strong constitution,
rooted in custom, of its manor England, in its social development, got quite as
much start of its neighbors, as it obtained
precedence over them politically through the early growth of parliamentary
institutions.
LEARNING AND LITERATURE TILL THE DEATH OF BEDE
|