CRISTO RAUL.ORG |
READING HALLTHE DOORS OF WISDOM |
A HISTORY OF CHINACHAPTER VI.THE HAN DYNASTY (206 B.C.-A.D. 220)1.
Development of the gentry-state
In 206 BC Liu Chi assumed the title of Emperor and
gave his dynasty the name of the Han Dynasty. After his death he was given as emperor
the name of Kao Tsu. The period of the Han dynasty
may be described as the beginning of the Chinese Middle Ages, while that of the
Ch'in dynasty represents the transition from antiquity to the Middle Ages; for
under the Han dynasty we meet in China with a new form of state, the
"gentry state". The feudalism of ancient times has come definitely to
its end.
Emperor Kao Tsu came from
eastern China, and his family seems to have been a peasant family; in any case
it did not belong to the old nobility. After his destruction of his strongest
rival, the removal of the kings who had made themselves independent in the last
years of the Ch'in dynasty was a relatively easy task for the new autocrat,
although these struggles occupied the greater part of his reign. A much more
difficult question, however, faced him: How was the empire to be governed? Kao Tsu's old friends and fellow-countrymen, who had helped him
into power, had been rewarded by appointment as generals or high officials.
Gradually he got rid of those who had been his best comrades, as so many
upstart rulers have done before and after him in every country in the world. An
emperor does not like to be reminded of a very humble past, and he is liable
also to fear the rivalry of men who formerly were his equals. It is evident
that little attention was paid to theories of administration; policy was
determined mainly by practical considerations. Kao Tsu allowed many laws and regulations to remain in force, including the prohibition
of Confucianist writings. On the other hand, he
reverted to the allocation of fiefs, though not to old noble families but to
his relatives and some of his closest adherents, generally men of inferior
social standing. Thus a mixed administration came into being: part of the empire
was governed by new feudal princes, and another part split up into provinces
and prefectures and placed directly under the central power through its
officials.
But whence came the officials? Kao Tsu and his supporters, as farmers from eastern China, looked down upon the trading
population to which farmers always regard themselves as superior. The merchants
were ignored as potential officials although they had often enough held
official appointments under the former dynasty. The second group from which
officials had been drawn under the Ch'in was that of the army officers, but
their military functions had now, of course, fallen to Kao Tsu's soldiers. The emperor had little faith, however, in the loyalty of officers,
even of his own, and apart from that he would have had first to create a new
administrative organization for them. Accordingly he turned to another class
which had come into existence, the class later called the gentry, which in
practice had the power already in its hands.
The term "gentry" has no direct parallel in
Chinese texts; the later terms "shen-shih"
and "chin-shen" do not quite cover this
concept. The basic unit of the gentry class are families, not individuals. Such
families often derive their origin from branches of the Chou nobility. But
other gentry families were of different and more recent origin in respect to
land ownership. Some late Chou and Ch'in officials of non-noble origin had
become wealthy and had acquired land; the same was true for wealthy merchants
and finally, some non-noble farmers who were successful in one or another way,
bought additional land reaching the size of large holdings. All
"gentry" families owned substantial estates in the provinces which
they leased to tenants on a kind of contract basis. The tenants, therefore,
cannot be called "serfs" although their factual position often was
not different from the position of serfs. The rents of these tenants, usually
about half the gross produce, are the basis of the livelihood of the gentry.
One part of a gentry family normally lives in the country on a small home farm
in order to be able to collect the rents. If the family can acquire more land
and if this new land is too far away from the home farm to make collection of
rents easy, a new home farm is set up under the control of another branch of
the family. But the original home remains to be regarded as the real family
centre.
In a typical gentry family, another branch of the
family is in the capital or in a provincial administrative centre in official positions.
These officials at the same time are the most highly educated members of the
family and are often called the "literati". There are also always
individual family members who are not interested in official careers or who
failed in their careers and live as free "literati" either in the big
cities or on the home farms. It seems, to judge from much later sources, that
the families assisted their most able members to enter the official careers,
while those individuals who were less able were used in the administration of
the farms. This system in combination with the strong familism of the Chinese, gave a double security to the gentry families. If difficulties
arose in the estates either by attacks of bandits or by war or other
catastrophes, the family members in official positions could use their
influence and power to restore the property in the provinces. If, on the other
hand, the family members in official positions lost their positions or even
their lives by displeasing the court, the home branch could always find ways to
remain untouched and could, in a generation or two, recruit new members and
regain power and influence in the government. Thus, as families, the gentry was
secure, although failures could occur to individuals. There are many gentry
families who remained in the ruling élite for many centuries, some over more
than a thousand years, weathering all vicissitudes of life. Some authors
believe that Chinese leading families generally pass through a three- or
four-generation cycle: a family member by his official position is able to
acquire much land, and his family moves upward. He is able to give the best
education and other facilities to his sons who lead a good life. But either
these sons or the grandsons are spoiled and lazy; they begin to lose their
property and status. The family moves downward, until in the fourth or fifth
generation a new rise begins. Actual study of families seems to indicate that
this is not true. The main branch of the family retains its position over
centuries. But some of the branch families, created often by the less able
family members, show a tendency towards downward social mobility.
It is clear from the above that a gentry family should
be interested in having a fair number of children. The more sons they have, the
more positions of power the family can occupy and thus, the more secure it will
be; the more daughters they have, the more "political" marriages they
can conclude, i.e. marriages with
sons of other gentry families in positions of influence. Therefore, gentry
families in China tend to be, on the average, larger than ordinary families,
while in our Western countries the leading families usually were smaller than
the lower class families. This means that gentry families produced more
children than was necessary to replenish the available leading positions; thus,
some family members had to get into lower positions and had to lose status. In
view of this situation it was very difficult for lower class families to
achieve access into this gentry group. In European countries the leading élite
did not quite replenish their ranks in the next generation, so that there was
always some chance for the lower classes to move up into leading ranks. The
gentry society was, therefore, a comparably stable society with little upward
social mobility but with some downward mobility. As a whole and for reasons of
gentry self-interest, the gentry stood for stability and against change.
The gentry members in the bureaucracy collaborated closely
with one another because they were tied together by bonds of blood or marriage.
It was easy for them to find good tutors for their children, because a pupil
owed a debt of gratitude to his teacher and a child from a gentry family could
later on nicely repay this debt; often, these teachers themselves were members
of other gentry families. It was easy for sons of the gentry to get into
official positions, because the people who had to recommend them for office
were often related to them or knew the position of their family. In Han time,
local officials had the duty to recommend young able men; if these men turned
out to be good, the officials were rewarded, if not they were blamed or even
punished. An official took less of a chance, if he recommended a son of an
influential family, and he obliged such a candidate so that he could later
count on his help if he himself should come into difficulties. When, towards the
end of the second century BC, a kind of examination system was introduced, this
attitude was not basically changed.
The country branch of the family by the fact that it
controlled large tracts of land, supplied also the logical tax collectors: they
had the standing and power required for this job. Even if they were appointed
in areas other than their home country (a rule which later was usually
applied), they knew the gentry families of the other district or were related
to them and got their support by appointing their members as their assistants.
Gentry society continued from Kao Tsu's time to 1948, but it went through a number of phases of development and changed
considerably in time. We will later outline some of the most important changes.
In general the number of politically leading gentry families was around one
hundred (texts often speak of "the hundred families" in this time)
and they were concentrated in the capital; the most important home seats of
these families in Han time were close to the capital and east of it or in the
plains of eastern China, at that time the main centre of grain production.
We regard roughly the first one thousand years of
"Gentry Society" as the period of the Chinese "Middle
Ages", beginning with the Han dynasty; the preceding time of the Ch'in was
considered as a period of transition, a time in which the feudal period of
"Antiquity" came to a formal end and a new organization of society
began to become visible. Even those authors who do not accept a sociological
classification of periods and many authors who use Marxist categories, believe
that with Ch'in and Han a new era in Chinese history began.
2.
Situation of the Hsiung-nu
empire; its relation to the Han empire. Incorporation of South China
In the time of the Ch'in dynasty there had already
come into unpleasant prominence north of the Chinese frontier the tribal union,
then relatively small, of the Hsiung-nu. Since then,
the Hsiung-nu empire had destroyed the federation of
the Yüeh-chih tribes (some of which seem to have been
of Indo-European language stock) and incorporated their people into their own
federation; they had conquered also the less well organized eastern pastoral
tribes, the Tung-hu and thus had become a formidable
power. Everything goes to show that it had close relations with the territories
of northern China. Many Chinese seem to have migrated to the Hsiung-nu empire, where they were welcome as artisans and
probably also as farmers; but above all they were needed for the staffing of a
new state administration. The scriveners in the newly introduced state
secretariat were Chinese and wrote Chinese, for at that time the Hsiung-nu apparently had no written language. There were
Chinese serving as administrators and court officials, and even as instructors
in the army administration, teaching the art of warfare against non-nomads. But
what was the purpose of all this? Mao Tun, the second
ruler of the Hsiung-nu, and his first successors
undoubtedly intended ultimately to conquer China, exactly as many other
northern peoples after them planned to do, and a few of them did. The main
purpose of this was always to bring large numbers of peasants under the rule of
the nomad rulers and so to solve, once for all, the problem of the provision of
additional winter food. Everything that was needed, and everything that seemed
to be worth trying to get as they grew more civilized, would thus be obtained
better and more regularly than by raids or by tedious commercial negotiations.
But if China was to be conquered and ruled there must exist a state
organization of equal authority to hers; the Hsiung-nu
ruler must himself come forward as Son of Heaven and develop a court ceremonial
similar to that of a Chinese emperor. Thus the basis of the organization of the Hsiung-nu state lay in its rivalry with the neighboring
China; but the details naturally corresponded to the special nature of the Hsiung-nu social system. The young Hsiung-nu
feudal state differed from the ancient Chinese feudal state not only in
depending on a nomad economy with only supplementary agriculture, but also in
possessing, in addition to a whole class of nobility and another of commoners,
a stratum of slavery to be analyzed further below. Similar to the Chou state,
the Hsiung-nu state contained, especially around the
ruler, an element of court bureaucracy which, however, never developed far
enough to replace the basically feudal character of administration.
Thus Kao Tsu was faced in
Mao Tun not with a mere nomad chieftain but with the
most dangerous of enemies, and Kao Tsu's policy had to
be directed to preventing any interference of the Hsiung-nu
in North Chinese affairs, and above all to preventing alliances between Hsiung-nu and Chinese. Hsiung-nu
alone, with their technique of horsemen's warfare, would scarcely have been
equal to the permanent conquest of the fortified towns of the north and the
Great Wall, although they controlled a population which may have been in excess
of 2,000,000 people. But they might have succeeded with Chinese aid. Actually a
Chinese opponent of Kao Tsu had already come to terms
with Mao Tun, and in 200 BC Kao Tsu was very near suffering disaster in northern Shansi, as a result of which China
would have come under the rule of the Hsiung-nu. But
it did not come to that, and Mao Tun made no further
attempt, although the opportunity came several times. Apparently the policy
adopted by his court was not imperialistic but national, in the uncorrupted
sense of the word. It was realized that a country so thickly populated as China
could only be administered from a centre within China. The Hsiung-nu
would thus have had to abandon their home territory and rule in China itself.
That would have meant abandoning the flocks, abandoning nomad life, and turning
into Chinese. The main supporters of the national policy, the first principle
of which was loyalty to the old ways of life, seem to have been the tribal
chieftains. Mao Tun fell in with their view, and the Hsiung-nu maintained their state as long as they adhered to
that principle—for some seven hundred years. Other nomad peoples, Toba,
Mongols, and Manchus, followed the opposite policy,
and before long they were caught in the mechanism of the much more highly
developed Chinese economy and culture, and each of them disappeared from the
political scene in the course of a century or so.
The national line of policy of the Hsiung-nu
did not at all mean an end of hostilities and raids on Chinese territory, so
that Kao Tsu declared himself ready to give the Hsiung-nu the foodstuffs and clothing materials they needed
if they would make an end of their raids. A treaty to this effect was
concluded, and sealed by the marriage of a Chinese princess with Mao Tun. This
was the first international treaty in the Far East between two independent
powers mutually recognized as equals, and the forms of international diplomacy
developed in this time remained the standard forms for the next thousand years.
The agreement was renewed at the accession of each new ruler, but was never
adhered to entirely by either side. The needs of the Hsiung-nu
increased with the expansion of their empire and the growing luxury of their
court; the Chinese, on the other hand, wanted to give as little as possible,
and no doubt they did all they could to cheat the Hsiung-nu.
Thus, in spite of the treaties the Hsiung-nu raids
went on. With China's progressive consolidation, the voluntary immigration of
Chinese into the Hsiung-nu empire came to an end, and
the Hsiung-nu actually began to kidnap Chinese
subjects. These were the main features of the relations between Chinese and Hsiung-nu almost until 100 BC.
In the extreme south, around the present-day Canton,
another independent empire had been formed in the years of transition, under
the leadership of a Chinese. The narrow basis of this realm was no doubt provided
by the trading colonies, but the indigenous population of Yüeh tribes was insufficiently civilized for the building up of a state that could
have maintained itself against China. Kao Tsu sent a
diplomatic mission to the ruler of this state, and invited him to place himself
under Chinese suzerainty (196 BC). The ruler realized that he could offer no
serious resistance, while the existing circumstances guaranteed him virtual
independence and he yielded to Kao Tsu without a
struggle.
3.
Brief feudal reaction. Consolidation of the gentry
Kao Tsu died in 195 BC. From
then to 179 the actual ruler was his widow, the empress Lü,
while children were officially styled emperors. The empress tried to remove all
the representatives of the emperor's family and to replace them with members of
her own family. To secure her position she revived the feudal system, but she
met with strong resistance from the dynasty and its supporters who already
belonged in many cases to the new gentry, and who did not want to find their
position jeopardized by the creation of new feudal lords.
On the death of the empress her opponents rose, under
the leadership of Kao Tsu's family. Every member of
the empress's family was exterminated, and a son of Kao Tsu,
known later under the name of Wen Ti (Emperor Wen), came to the throne. He reigned from 179 to 157 BC.
Under him there were still many fiefs, but with the limitation which the
emperor Kao Tsu had laid down shortly before his
death: only members of the imperial family should receive fiefs, to which the
title of King was attached. Thus all the more important fiefs were in the hands
of the imperial family, though this did not mean that rivalries came to an end.
On the whole Wen Ti's period of rule passed in comparative peace. For the
first time since the beginning of Chinese history, great areas of continuous
territory were under unified rule, without unending internal warfare such as
had existed under Shih Huang-ti and Kao Tsu. The creation of so extensive a region of peace
produced great economic advance. The burdens that had lain on the peasant
population were reduced, especially since under Wen Ti the court was very frugal. The population grew and cultivated fresh land, so
that production increased and with it the exchange of goods. The most
outstanding sign of this was the abandonment of restrictions on the minting of
copper coin, in order to prevent deflation through insufficiency of payment
media. As a consequence more taxes were brought in, partly in kind, partly in
coin, and this increased the power of the central government. The new gentry
streamed into the towns, their standard of living rose, and they made
themselves more and more into a class apart from the general population. As
people free from material cares, they were able to devote themselves to
scholarship. They went back to the old writings and studied them once more.
They even began to identify themselves with the nobles of feudal times, to
adopt the rules of good behavior and the ceremonial described in the Confucianist books, and very gradually, as time went on, to
make these their textbooks of good form. From this point the Confucianist ideals first began to penetrate the official
class recruited from the gentry, and then the state organization itself. It was
expected that an official should be versed in Confucianism, and schools were
set up for Confucianist education. Around 100 BC this
led to the introduction of the examination system, which gradually became the
one method of selection of new officials. The system underwent many changes,
but remained in operation in principle until 1904. The object of the
examinations was not to test job efficiency but command of the ideals of the
gentry and knowledge of the literature inculcating them: this was regarded as
sufficient qualification for any position in the service of the state.
In theory this path to training of character and to
admission to the state service was open to every "respectable"
citizen. Of the traditional four "classes" of Chinese society, only
the first two, officials (shih) and farmers (nung)
were always regarded as fully "respectable" (liang-min).
Members of the other two classes, artisans (kung) and merchants (shang), were under numerous restrictions. Below these were
classes of "lowly people" (ch'ien-min) and
below these the slaves which were not part of society proper. The privileges
and obligations of these categories were soon legally fixed. In practice,
during the first thousand years of the existence of the examination system no
peasant had a chance to become an official by means of the examinations. In the
Han period the provincial officials had to propose suitable young persons for examination, and so for admission to the state
service, as was already mentioned. In addition, schools had been instituted for
the sons of officials; it is interesting to note that there were, again and
again, complaints about the low level of instruction in these schools.
Nevertheless, through these schools all sons of officials, whatever their
capacity or lack of capacity, could become officials in their turn. In spite of
its weaknesses, the system had its good side. It inoculated a class of people
with ideals that were unquestionably of high ethical value. The Confucian moral
system gave a Chinese official or any member of the gentry a spiritual attitude
and an outward bearing which in their best representatives has always commanded
respect, an integrity that has always preserved its possessors, and in consequence
Chinese society as a whole, from moral collapse, from spiritual nihilism, and
has thus contributed to the preservation of Chinese cultural values in spite of
all foreign conquerors.
In the time of Wen Ti and
especially of his successors, the revival at court of the Confucianist ritual and of the earlier Heaven-worship proceeded steadily. The sacrifices
supposed to have been performed in ancient times, the ritual supposed to have
been prescribed for the emperor in the past, all this was reintroduced.
Obviously much of it was spurious: much of the old texts had been lost, and
when fragments were found they were arbitrarily completed. Moreover, the old
writing was difficult to read and difficult to understand; thus various things
were read into the texts without justification. The new Confucians who came
forward as experts in the moral code were very different men from their
predecessors; above all, like all their contemporaries, they were strongly
influenced by the shamanistic magic that had developed in the Ch'in period.
Wen Ti's reign had brought economic advance and
prosperity; intellectually it had been a period of renaissance, but like every
such period it did not simply resuscitate what was old, but filled the ancient
moulds with an entirely new content. Socially the period had witnessed the
consolidation of the new upper class, the gentry, who copied the mode of life
of the old nobility. This is seen most clearly in the field of law. In the time
of the Legalists the first steps had been taken in the codification of the
criminal law. They clearly intended these laws to serve equally for all classes
of the people. The Ch'in code which was supposedly Li K'uei's code, was used in the Han period, and was extensively elaborated by Siao Ho (died 193 BC) and others. This code consisted of
two volumes of the chief laws for grave cases, one of mixed laws for the less
serious cases, and six volumes on the imposition of penalties. In the Han
period "decisions" were added, so that about AD 200 the code had
grown to 26,272 paragraphs with over 17,000,000 words. The collection then
consisted of 960 volumes. This colossal code has been continually revised,
abbreviated, or expanded, and under its last name of "Collected Statues of
the Manchu Dynasty" it retained its validity down to the present century.
Alongside this collection there was another book that
came to be regarded and used as a book of precedences.
The great Confucianist philosopher Tung Chung-shu (179-104 BC), a firm supporter of the ideology of the
new gentry class, declared that the classic Confucianist writings, and especially the book Ch'un-ch'iu,
"Annals of Spring and Autumn", attributed to Confucius himself, were
essentially books of legal decisions. They contained "cases" and
Confucius's decisions of them. Consequently any case at law that might arise
could be decided by analogy with the cases contained in "Annals of Spring
and Autumn". Only an educated person, of course, a member of the gentry,
could claim that his action should be judged by the decisions of Confucius and
not by the code compiled for the common people, for Confucius had expressly
stated that his rules were intended only for the upper class. Thus, right down
to modern times an educated person could be judged under regulations different
from those applicable to the common people, or if judged on the basis of the
laws, he had to expect a special treatment. The principle of the "equality
before the law" which the Legalists had advocated and which fitted well into
the absolutistic, totalitarian system of the Ch'in, had been attacked by the
feudal nobility at that time and was attacked by the new gentry of the Han
time. Legalist thinking remained an important undercurrent for many centuries
to come, but application of the equalitarian principle was from now on never
seriously considered.
Against the growing influence of the officials
belonging to the gentry there came a last reaction. It came as a reply to the
attempt of a representative of the gentry to deprive the feudal princes of the
whole of their power. In the time of Wen Ti's successor a number of feudal kings formed an alliance
against the emperor, and even invited the Hsiung-nu
to join them. The Hsiung-nu did not do so, because
they saw that the rising had no prospect of success, and it was quelled. After
that the feudal princes were steadily deprived of rights. They were divided
into two classes, and only privileged ones were permitted to live in the
capital, the others being required to remain in their domains. At first, the
area was controlled by a "minister" of the prince, an official of the
state; later the area remained under normal administration and the feudal
prince kept only an empty title; the tax income of a certain number of families
of an area was assigned to him and transmitted to him by normal administrative
channels. Often, the number of assigned families was fictional in that the
actual income was from far fewer families. This system differs from the Near
Eastern system in which also no actual enfeoffment took place, but where deserving men were granted the right to collect
themselves the taxes of a certain area with certain numbers of families.
Soon after this the whole government was given the
shape which it continued to have until AD 220, and which formed the point of
departure for all later forms of government. At the head of the state was the
emperor, in theory the holder of absolute power in the state restricted only by
his responsibility towards "Heaven", i.e. he had to follow and to
enforce the basic rules of morality, otherwise "Heaven" would
withdraw its "mandate", the legitimation of
the emperor's rule, and would indicate this withdrawal by sending natural
catastrophes. Time and again we find emperors publicly accusing themselves for
their faults when such catastrophes occurred; and to draw the emperor's
attention to actual or made-up calamities or celestrial irregularities was one way to criticize an emperor and to force him to change
his behavior. There are two other indications which show that Chinese
emperors—excepting a few individual cases—at least in the first ten centuries
of gentry society were not despots: it can be proved that in some fields the
responsibility for governmental action did not lie with the emperor but with
some of his ministers. Secondly, the emperor was bound by the law code: he
could not change it nor abolish it. We know of cases in which the ruler
disregarded the code, but then tried to "defend" his arbitrary
action. Each new dynasty developed a new law code, usually changing only
details of the punishment, not the basic regulations. Rulers could issue
additional "regulations", but these, too, had to be in the spirit of
the general code and the existing moral norms. This situation has some
similarity to the situation in Muslim countries. At the ruler's side were three
counselors who had, however, no active functions. The real conduct of policy
lay in the hands of the "chancellor", or of one of the "nine
ministers". Unlike the practice with which we are familiar in the West,
the activities of the ministries (one of them being the court secretariat) were
concerned primarily with the imperial palace. As, however, the court
secretariat, one of the nine ministries, was at the same time a sort of
imperial statistical office, in which all economic, financial, and military
statistical material was assembled, decisions on issues of critical importance
for the whole country could and did come from it. The court, through the
Ministry of Supplies, operated mines and workshops in the provinces and
organized the labor service for public constructions. The court also controlled
centrally the conscription for the general military service. Beside the
ministries there was an extensive administration of the capital with its
military guards. The various parts of the country, including the lands given as
fiefs to princes, had a local administration, entirely independent of the
central government and more or less elaborated according to their size. The
regional administration was loosely associated with the central government
through a sort of primitive ministry of the interior, and similarly the Chinese
representatives in the protectorates, that is to say the foreign states which
had submitted to Chinese protective overlordship,
were loosely united with a sort of foreign ministry in the central government.
When a rising or a local war broke out, that was the affair of the officer of
the region concerned. If the regional troops were insufficient, those of the
adjoining regions were drawn upon; if even these were insufficient, a real
"state of war" came into being; that is to say, the emperor appointed
eight generals-in-chief, mobilized the imperial troops, and intervened. This
imperial army then had authority over the regional and feudal troops, the
troops of the protectorates, the guards of the capital, and those of the
imperial palace. At the end of the war the imperial army was demobilized and
the generals-in-chief were transferred to other posts.
In all this there gradually developed a division into
civil and military administration. A number of regions would make up a province
with a military governor, who was in a sense the representative of the imperial
army, and who was supposed to come into activity only in the event of war.
This administration of the Han period lacked the tight
organization that would make precise functioning possible. On the otherhand, an extremely important institution had already
come into existence in a primitive form. As central statistical authority, the
court secretariat had a special position within the ministries and supervised
the administration of the other offices. Thus there existed alongside the
executive a means of independent supervision of it, and the resulting rivalry
enabled the emperor or the chancellor to detect and eliminate irregularities.
Later, in the system of the T'ang period (AD 618-906),
this institution developed into an independent censorship, and the system was
given a new form as a "State and Court Secretariat", in which the
whole executive was comprised and unified. Towards the end of the T'ang period the permanent state of war necessitated the
permanent commissioning of the imperial generals-in-chief and of the military
governors, and as a result there came into existence a "Privy Council of
State", which gradually took over functions of the executive. The system
of administration in the Han and in the T'ang period
is shown in the following table:
There is no denying that according to our standard
this whole system was still elementary and "personal", that is to
say, attached to the emperor's person—though it should not be overlooked that
we ourselves are not yet far from a similar phase of development. To this day
the titles of not a few of the highest officers of state—the Lord Privy Seal,
for instance—recall that in the past their offices were conceived as concerned
purely with the personal service of the monarch. In one point, however, the Han
administrative set-up was quite modern: it already had a clear separation
between the emperor's private treasury and the state treasury; laws determined
which of the two received certain taxes and which had to make certain payments.
This separation, which in Europe occurred not until the late Middle Ages, in
China was abolished at the end of the Han Dynasty.
The picture changes considerably to the advantage of
the Chinese as soon as we consider the provincial administration. The governor
of a province, and each of his district officers or prefects, had a staff often
of more than a hundred officials. These officials were drawn from the province
or prefecture and from the personal friends of the administrator, and they were
appointed by the governor or the prefect. The staff was made up of officials
responsible for communications with the central or provincial administration
(private secretary, controller, finance officer), and a group of officials who
carried on the actual local administration. There were departments for
transport, finance, education, justice, medicine (hygiene), economic and
military affairs, market control, and presents (which had to be made to the
higher officials at the New Year and on other occasions). In addition to these
offices, organized in a quite modern style, there was an office for advising
the governor and another for drafting official documents and letters.
The interesting feature of this system is that the
provincial administration was de facto independent of the central
administration, and that the governor and even his prefects could rule like
kings in their regions, appointing and discharging as they chose. This was a
vestige of feudalism, but on the other hand it was a healthy check against
excessive centralization. It is thanks to this system that even the collapse of
the central power or the cutting off of a part of the empire did not bring the
collapse of the country. In a remote frontier town like Tunhuang,
on the border of Turkestan, the life of the local Chinese went on undisturbed
whether communication with the capital was maintained or was broken through
invasions by foreigners. The official sent from the centre would be liable at
any time to be transferred elsewhere; and he had to depend on the practical
knowledge of his subordinates, the members of the local families of the gentry.
These officials had the local government in their hands, and carried on the
administration of places like Tunhuang through a
thousand years and more. The Hsin family, for instance,
was living there in 50 BC and was still there in AD 950; and so were the Yin,
Ling-hu, Li, and K'ang families.
All the officials of the various offices or Ministries
were appointed under the state examination system, but they had no special
professional training; only for the more important subordinate posts were there
specialists, such as jurists, physicians, and so on. A change came towards the
end of the T'ang period, when a Department of
Commerce and Monopolies was set up; only specialists were appointed to it, and
it was placed directly under[Pg 86] the emperor. Except for this, any official
could be transferred from any ministry to any other without regard to his
experience.
4
Turkestan policy. End of the Hsiung-nu empire
In the two decades between 160 and 140 BC there had
been further trouble with the Hsiung-nu, though there
was no large-scale fighting. There was a fundamental change of policy under the
next emperor, Wu (or Wu Ti, 141-86 BC). The Chinese entered for the first time
upon an active policy against the Hsiung-nu. There
seem to have been several reasons for this policy, and several objectives. The
raids of the Hsiung-nu from the Ordos region and from
northern Shansi had shown themselves to be a direct menace to the capital and
to its extremely important hinterland. Northern Shansi is mountainous, with
deep ravines. A considerable army on horseback could penetrate some distance to
the south before attracting attention. Northern Shensi and the Ordos region are
steppe country, in which there were very few Chinese settlements and through
which an army of horsemen could advance very quickly. It was therefore
determined to push back the Hsiung-nu far enough to
remove this threat. It was also of importance to break the power of the Hsiung-nu in the province of Kansu, and to separate them as
far as possible from the Tibetans living in that region, to prevent any union
between those two dangerous adversaries. A third point of importance was the
safeguarding of caravan routes. The state, and especially the capital, had
grown rich through Wen Ti's policy. Goods streamed into the capital from all quarters. Commerce with
central Asia had particularly increased, bringing the products of the Middle
East to China. The caravan routes passed through western Shensi and Kansu to
eastern Turkestan, but at that time the Hsiung-nu
dominated the approaches to Turkestan and were in a position to divert the
trade to themselves or cut it off. The commerce brought profit not only to the
caravan traders, most of whom were probably foreigners, but to the officials in
the provinces and prefectures through which the routes passed. Thus the
officials in western China were interested in the trade routes being brought
under direct control, so that the caravans could arrive regularly and be immune
from robbery. Finally, the Chinese government may well have regarded it as
little to its honor to be still paying dues to the Hsiung-nu
and sending princesses to their rulers, now that China was incomparably
wealthier and stronger than at the time when that policy of appeasement had
begun.
The first active step taken was to try, in 133 BC, to
capture the head of the Hsiung-nu state, who was
called a shan-yü; but the shan-yü saw through the plan and escaped. There followed a period of continuous
fighting until 119 BC. The Chinese made countless attacks, without lasting
success. But the Hsiung-nu were weakened, one sign of
this being that there were dissensions after the death of the shan-yü Chün-ch'en, and in 127 BC
his son went over to the Chinese. Finally the Chinese altered their tactics,
advancing in 119 B.C. with a strong army of cavalry, which suffered enormous
losses but inflicted serious loss on the Hsiung-nu.
After that the Hsiung-nu withdrew farther to the
north, and the Chinese settled peasants in the important region of Kansu.
Meanwhile, in 125 BC, the famous Chang Ch'ien had returned. He had been sent in 138 to conclude an
alliance with the Yüeh-chih against the Hsiung-nu. The Yüeh-chih had
formerly been neighbors of the Hsiung-nu as far as
the Ala Shan region, but owing to defeat by the Hsiung-nu
their remnants had migrated to western Turkestan. Chang Ch'ien had followed them. Politically he had had no success, but he brought back
accurate information about the countries in the far west, concerning which
nothing had been known beyond the vague reports of merchants. Now it was learnt
whence the foreign goods came and whither the Chinese goods went. Chang Ch'ien's reports (which are one of the principal sources
for the history of central Asia at that remote time) strengthened the desire to
enter into direct and assured commercial relations with those distant
countries. The government evidently thought of getting this commerce into its
own hands. The way to do this was to impose "tribute" on the
countries concerned. The idea was that the missions bringing the annual
"tribute" would be a sort of state bartering commissions. The state
laid under tribute must supply specified goods at its own cost, and received in
return Chinese produce, the value of which was to be roughly equal to the
"tribute". Thus Chang Ch'ien's reports had
the result that, after the first successes against the Hsiung-nu,
there was increased interest in a central Asian policy. The greatest military
success were the campaigns of General Li Kuang-li to Ferghana in 104 and 102 BC. The result of the campaigns was
to bring under tribute all the small states in the Tarim basin and some of the states of western Turkestan. From now on not only foreign
consumer goods came freely into China, but with them a great number of other
things, notably plants such as grape, peach, pomegranate.
In 108 BC the western part of Korea was also
conquered. Korea was already an important transit region for the trade with
Japan. Thus this trade also came under the direct influence of the Chinese
government. Although this conquest represented a peril to the eastern
flank of the Hsiung-nu, it did not by any means mean
that they were conquered. The Hsiung-nu while
weakened evaded the Chinese pressure, but in 104 BC and again in 91 they
inflicted defeats on the Chinese. The Hsiung-nu were
indirectly threatened by Chinese foreign policy, for the Chinese concluded an
alliance with old enemies of the Hsiung-nu, the
Wu-sun, in the north of the Tarim basin. This made
the Tarim basin secure for the Chinese, and
threatened the Hsiung-nu with a new danger in their
rear. Finally the Chinese did all they could through intrigue, espionage, and
sabotage to promote disunity and disorder within the Hsiung-nu,
though it cannot be seen from the Chinese accounts how far the Chinese were
responsible for the actual conflicts and the continual changes of shan-yü. Hostilities against the Hsiung-nu
continued incessantly, after the death of Wu Ti, under his successor, so that
the Hsiung-nu were further weakened. In consequence
of this it was possible to rouse against them other tribes who until then had
been dependent on them—the Ting-ling in the north and the Wu-huan in the east. The internal difficulties of the Hsiung-nu increased further.
Wu Ti's active policy had
not been directed only against the Hsiung-nu. After
heavy fighting he brought southern China, with the region round Canton, and the
south-eastern coast, firmly under Chinese dominion—in this case again on
account of trade interests. No doubt there were already considerable colonies
of foreign merchants in Canton and other coastal towns, trading in Indian and
Middle East goods. The traders seem often to have been Sogdians.
The southern wars gave Wu Ti the control of the revenues from this commerce. He
tried several times to advance through Yünnan in
order to secure a better land route to India, but these attempts failed.
Nevertheless, Chinese influence became stronger in the south-west.
In spite of his long rule, Wu Ti did not leave an
adult heir, as the crown prince was executed, with many other persons, shortly
before Wu Ti's death. The crown prince had been
implicated in an alleged attempt by a large group of people to remove the
emperor by various sorts of magic. It is difficult to determine today what lay
behind this affair; probably it was a struggle between two cliques of the
gentry. Thus a regency council had to be set up for the young heir to the
throne; it included a member of a Hsiung-nu tribe.
The actual government was in the hands of a general and his clique until the
death of the heir to the throne, and at the beginning of his successor's reign.
At this time came the end of the Hsiung-nu
empire—a foreign event of the utmost importance. As a result of the continual disastrous
wars against the Chinese, in which not only many men but, especially, large
quantities of cattle fell into Chinese hands, the livelihood of the Hsiung-nu was seriously threatened; their troubles were
increased by plagues and by unusually severe winters. To these troubles were
added political difficulties, including unsettled questions in regard to the
succession to the throne. The result of all this was that the Hsiung-nu could no longer offer effective military
resistance to the Chinese. There were a number of shan-yü ruling contemporaneously as rivals, and one of them had to yield to the Chinese
in 58 BC; in 51 he came as a vassal to the Chinese court. The collapse of the Hsiung-nu empire was complete. After 58 BC the Chinese were
freed from all danger from that quarter and were able, for a time, to impose
their authority in Central Asia.
5.
Impoverishment. Cliques. End of the Dynasty
In other respects the Chinese were not doing as well
as might have been assumed. The wars carried on by Wu Ti and his successors had
been ruinous. The maintenance of large armies of occupation in the new regions,
especially in Turkestan, also meant a permanent drain on the national funds.
There was a special need for horses, for the people of the steppes could only
be fought by means of cavalry. As the Hsiung-nu were
supplying no horses, and the campaigns were not producing horses enough as
booty, the peasants had to rear horses for the government. Additional horses
were bought at very high prices, and apart from this the general financing of
the wars necessitated increased taxation of the peasants, a burden on agriculture
no less serious than was the enrolment of many peasants for military service.
Finally, the new external trade did not by any means bring the advantages that
had been hoped for. The tribute missions brought tribute but, to begin with,
this meant an obligation to give presents in return; moreover, these missions
had to be fed and housed in the capital, often for months, as the official
receptions took place only on New Year's Day. Their maintenance entailed much
expense, and meanwhile the members of the missions traded privately with the
inhabitants and the merchants of the capital, buying things they needed and
selling things they had brought in addition to the tribute. The tribute itself
consisted mainly of "precious articles", which meant strange or rare things
of no practical value. The emperor made use of them as elements of personal
luxury, or made presents of some of them to deserving officials. The gifts
offered by the Chinese in return consisted mainly of silk. Silk was received by
the government as a part of the tax payments and formed an important element of
the revenue of the state. It now went abroad without bringing in any
corresponding return. The private trade carried on by the members of the
missions was equally unserviceable to the Chinese. It, too, took from them
goods of economic value, silk and gold, which went abroad in exchange for
luxury articles of little or no economic importance, such as glass, precious
stones, or stud horses, which in no way benefited the general population. Thus
in this last century BC China's economic situation grew steadily and fairly
rapidly worse. The peasants, more heavily taxed than ever, were impoverished,
and yet the exchequer became not fuller but emptier, so that gold began even to
be no longer available for payments. Wu Ti was aware of the situation and
called different groups together to discuss the problems of economics. Under
the name "Discussions on Salt and Iron" the gist of these talks is
preserved and shows that one group under the leadership of Sang Hung-yang
(143-80 BC) was business-oriented and thinking in economic terms, while their
opponents, mainly Confucianists, regarded the
situation mainly as a moral crisis. Sang proposed an "equable
transportation" and a "standardization" system and favoured other state monopolies and controls; these ideas
were taken up later and continued to be discussed, again and again.
Already under Wu Ti there had been signs of a
development which now appeared constantly in Chinese history. Among the new gentry,
families entered into alliances with each other, sealed their mutual allegiance
by matrimonial unions, and so formed large cliques. Each clique made it its
concern to get the most important government positions into its hands, so that
it should itself control the government. Under Wu Ti, for example, almost all
the important generals had belonged to a certain clique, which remained
dominant under his two successors. Two of the chief means of attaining power
were for such a clique to give the emperor a girl from its ranks as wife, and
to see to it that all the eunuchs around the emperor should be persons
dependent on the clique. Eunuchs came generally from the poorer classes; they
were launched at court by members of the great cliques, or quite openly presented
to the emperor.
The chief influence of the cliques lay, however, in
the selection of officials. It is not surprising that the officials recommended
only sons of people in their own clique—their family or its closest associates.
On top of all this, the examiners were in most cases themselves members of the
same families to which the provincial officials belonged. Thus it was made
doubly certain that only those candidates who were to the liking of the
dominant group among the gentry should pass.
Surrounded by these cliques, the emperors became in
most cases powerless figureheads. At times energetic rulers were able to play
off various cliques against each other, and so to acquire personal power; but the
weaker emperors found themselves entirely in the hands of cliques. Not a few
emperors in China were removed by cliques which they had attempted to resist;
and various dynasties were brought to their end by the cliques; this was the
fate of the Han dynasty.
The beginning of its fall came with the activities of
the widow of the emperor Yüan Ti. She virtually ruled
in the name of her eighteen-year-old son, the emperor Ch'eng Ti (32-7 BC), and placed all her brothers, and also her nephew, Wang Mang, in the principal government posts. They succeeded at
first in either removing the strongest of the other cliques or bringing them
into dependence. Within the Wang family the nephew Wang Mang steadily advanced, securing direct supporters even in some branches of the
imperial family; these personages declared their readiness to join him in
removing the existing line of the imperial house. When Ch'eng Ti died without issue, a young nephew of his (Ai Ti, 6-1 BC) was placed on the
throne by Wang Mang, and during this period the power
of the Wangs and their allies grew further, until all
their opponents had been removed and the influence of the imperial family very greatly reduced. When Ai Ti died, Wang Mang placed an eight-year-old boy on the throne, himself
acting as regent; four years later the boy fell ill and died, probably with
Wang Mang's aid. Wang Mang now chose a one-year-old baby, but soon after he felt that the time had come
for officially assuming the rulership. In AD 8 he
dethroned the baby, ostensibly at Heaven's command, and declared himself
emperor and first of the Hsin ("new")
dynasty. All the members of the old imperial family in the capital were removed
from office and degraded to commoners, with the exception of those who had
already been supporting Wang Mang. Only those members
who held unimportant posts at a distance remained untouched.
Wang Mang's "usurpation" is unusual from two points of view. First, he paid great
attention to public opinion and induced large masses of the population to write
petitions to the court asking the Han ruler to abdicate; he even fabricated
"heavenly omina" in his own favour and against the Han dynasty in order to get wide
support even from intellectuals. Secondly, he inaugurated a formal abdication
ceremony, culminating in the transfer of the imperial seal to himself. This
ceremony became standard for the next centuries. The seal was made of a
precious stone, once presented to the Ch'in dynasty ruler before he ascended
the throne. From now on, the possessor of this seal was the legitimate ruler.
6.
The pseudo-socialistic dictatorship. Revolt of the
"Red Eyebrows"
Wang Mang's dynasty lasted
only from AD 9 to 23; but it was one of the most stirring periods of Chinese
history. It is difficult to evaluate Wang Mang,
because all we know about him stems from sources hostile towards him. Yet we
gain the impression that some of his innovations, such as the legalization of
enthronement through the transfer of the seal; the changes in the
administration of provinces and in the bureaucratic set-up in the capital; and
even some of his economic measures were so highly regarded that they were
retained or re-introduced, although this happened in some instances centuries
later and without mentioning Wang Mang's name. But
most of his policies and actions were certainly neither accepted nor
acceptable. He made use of every conceivable resource in order to secure power
to his clique. As far as possible he avoided using open force, and resorted to
a high-level propaganda. Confucianism, the philosophic basis of the power of
the gentry, served him as a bait; he made use of the so-called "old
character school" for his purposes. When, after the holocaust of books, it
was desired to collect the ancient classics again, texts were found under
strange circumstances in the walls of Confucius's house; they were written in
an archaic script. The people who occupied themselves with these books were
called the old character school. The texts came under suspicion; most scholars
had little belief in their genuineness. Wang Mang,
however, and his creatures energetically supported the cult of these ancient
writings. The texts were edited and issued, and in the process, as can now be
seen, certain things were smuggled into them that fitted in well with Wang Mang's intentions. He even had other texts reissued with
falsifications. He now represented himself in all his actions as a man who did
with the utmost precision the things which the books reported of rulers or
ministers of ancient times. As regent he had declared that his model was the
brother of the first emperor of the Chou dynasty; as emperor he took for his
exemplar one of the mythical emperors of ancient China; of his new laws he
claimed that they were simply revivals of decrees of the golden age. In all
this he appealed to the authority of literature that had been tampered with to
suit his aims. Actually, such laws had never before been customary; either Wang Mang completely misinterpreted passages in an ancient
text to suit his purpose, or he had dicta that suited him smuggled into the
text. There can be no question that Wang Mang and his
accomplices began by deliberately falsifying and deceiving. However, as time
went on, he probably began to believe in his own frauds.
Wang Mang's great series of
certain laws has brought him the name of "the first Socialist on the
throne of China". But closer consideration reveals that these measures,
ostensibly and especially aimed at the good of the poor, were in reality
devised simply in order to fill the imperial exchequer and to consolidate the
imperial power. When we read of the turning over of great landed estates to the
state, do we not imagine that we are faced with a modern land reform? But this
applied only to the wealthiest of all the landowners, who were to be deprived
in this way of their power. The prohibition of private slave-owning had a
similar purpose, the state reserving to itself the right to keep slaves.
Moreover, landless peasants were to receive land to till, at the expense of
those who possessed too much. This admirable law, however, was not intended
seriously to be carried into effect. Instead, the setting up of a system of
state credits for peasants held out the promise, in spite of rather reduced
interest rates, of important revenue. The peasants had never been in a position
to pay back their private debts together with the usurious interest, but there
were at least opportunities of coming to terms with a private usurer, whereas
the state proved a merciless creditor. It could dispossess the peasant, and
either turn his property into a state farm, convey it to another owner, or make
the peasant a state slave. Thus this measure worked against the interest of the
peasants, as did the state monopoly of the exploitation of mountains and lakes.
"Mountains and lakes" meant the uncultivated land around settlements,
the "village commons", where people collected firewood or went
fishing. They now had to pay money for fishing rights and for the right to
collect wood, money for the emperor's exchequer. The same purpose lay behind
the wine, salt, and iron tool monopolies. Enormous revenues came to the state
from the monopoly of minting coin, when old metal coin of full value was called
in and exchanged for debased coin. Another modern-sounding institution, that of
the "equalization offices", was supposed to buy cheap goods in times
of plenty in order to sell them to the people in times of scarcity at similarly
low prices, so preventing want and also preventing excessive price
fluctuations. In actual fact these state offices formed a new source of profit,
buying cheaply and selling as dearly as possible.
Thus the character of these laws was in no way
socialistic; nor, however, did they provide an El Dorado for the state
finances, for Wang Mang's officials turned all the
laws to their private advantage. The revenues rarely reached the capital; they
vanished into the pockets of subordinate officials. The result was a further
serious lowering of the level of existence of the peasant population, with no
addition to the financial resources of the state. Yet Wang Mang had great need of money, because he attached importance to display and because
he was planning a new war. He aimed at the final destruction of the Hsiung-nu, so that access to central Asia should no longer
be precarious and it should thus be possible to reduce the expense of the
military administration of Turkestan. The war would also distract popular
attention from the troubles at home. By way of preparation for war, Wang Mang sent a mission to the Hsiung-nu
with dishonouring proposals, including changes in the
name of the Hsiung-nu and in the title of the shan-yü. The name Hsiung-nu was
to be given the insulting change of Hsiang-nu, meaning "subjugated
slaves". The result was that risings of the Hsiung-nu
took place, whereupon Wang Mang commanded that the
whole of their country should be partitioned among fifteen shan-yü and declared the country to be a Chinese province. Since this declaration had
no practical result, it robbed Wang Mang of the
increased prestige he had sought and only further infuriated the Hsiung-nu. Wang Mang concentrated
a vast army on the frontier. Meanwhile he lost the whole of the possessions in
Turkestan.
But before Wang Mang's campaign against the Hsiung-nu could begin, the
difficulties at home grew steadily worse. In A.D. 12 Wang Mang felt obliged to abrogate all his reform legislation because it could not be
carried into effect; and the economic situation proved more lamentable than
ever. There were continual risings, which culminated in AD 18 in a great
popular insurrection, a genuine revolutionary rising of the peasants, whose
distress had grown beyond bearing through Wang Mang's ill-judged measures. The rebels called themselves "Red Eyebrows";
they had painted their eyebrows red by way of badge and in order to bind their
members indissolubly to their movement. The nucleus of this rising was a secret
society. Such secret societies, usually are harmless, but may, in emergency
situations, become an immensely effective instrument in the hands of the rural
population. The secret societies then organize the peasants, in order to
achieve a forcible settlement of the matter in dispute. Occasionally, however,
the movement grows far beyond its leaders' original objective and becomes a
popular revolutionary movement, directed against the whole ruling class. That
is what happened on this occasion. Vast swarms of peasants marched to the
capital, killing all officials and people of position on their way. The troops
sent against them by Wang Mang either went over to
the Red Eyebrows or copied them, plundering wherever they could and killing
officials. Owing to the appalling mass murders and the fighting, the forces
placed by Wang Mang along the frontier against the Hsiung-nu received no reinforcements and, instead of
attacking the Hsiung-nu, themselves went over to
plundering, so that ultimately the army simply disintegrated. Fortunately for
China, the shan-yü of the time did not take advantage
of his opportunity, perhaps because his position within the Hsiung-nu
empire was too insecure.
Scarcely had the popular rising begun when descendants
of the deposed Han dynasty appeared and tried to secure the support of the
upper class. They came forward as fighters against the usurper Wang Mang and as defenders of the old social order against the
revolutionary masses. But the armies which these Han princes were able to
collect were no better than those of the other sides. They, too, consisted of
poor and hungry peasants, whose aim was to get money or goods by robbery; they
too, plundered and murdered more than they fought.
However, one prince by the name of Liu Hsiu gradually gained the upper hand. The basis of his
power was the district of Nanyang in Honan, one of
the wealthiest agricultural centres of China at that
time and also the centre of iron and steel production. The big landowners, the
gentry of Nanyang, joined him, and the prince's party
conquered the capital. Wang Mang, placing entire
faith in his sanctity, did not flee; he sat in his robes in the throne-room and
recited the ancient writings, convinced that he would overcome his adversaries
by the power of his words. But a soldier cut off his head (AD 22). The skull was
kept for two hundred years in the imperial treasury. The fighting,
nevertheless, went on. Various branches of the prince's party fought one
another, and all of them fought the Red Eyebrows. In those years millions of
men came to their end. Finally, in AD 24, Liu Hsiu prevailed, becoming the first emperor of the second Han dynasty, also called
the Later Han dynasty; his name as emperor was Kuang-wu Ti (AD 25-57).
7.
Reaction and Restoration: the Later Han dynasty
Within the country the period that followed was one of
reaction and restoration. The massacres of the preceding years had so reduced
the population that there was land enough for the peasants who remained alive.
Moreover, their lords and the money-lenders of the towns were generally no longer
alive, so that many peasants had become free of debt. The government was
transferred from Sian to Loyang, in the present province of Honan. This brought
the capital nearer to the great wheat-producing regions, so that the transport
of grain and other taxes in kind to the capital was cheapened. Soon this
cleared foundation was covered by a new stratum, a very sparse one, of great
landowners who were supporters and members of the new imperial house, largely
descendants of the landowners of the earlier Han period. At first they were not
much in evidence, but they gained power more and more rapidly. In spite of
this, the first half-century of the Later Han period was one of good conditions
on the land and economic recovery.
8.
Hsiung-nu policy
In foreign policy the first period of the Later Han
dynasty was one of extraordinary success, both in the extreme south and in the
question of the Hsiung-nu. During the period of Wang Mang's rule and the fighting connected with it, there had
been extensive migration to the south and south-west. Considerable regions of
Chinese settlement had come into existence in Yünnan and even in Annam and Tongking, and a series of
campaigns under General Ma Yüan (14 BC-AD 49) now
added these regions to the territory of the empire. These wars were carried on
with relatively small forces, as previously in the Canton region, the natives
being unable to offer serious resistance owing to their inferiority in
equipment and civilization. The hot climate, however, to which the Chinese soldiers
were unused, was hard for them to endure.
The Hsiung-nu, in spite of
internal difficulties, had regained considerable influence in Turkestan during
the reign of Wang Mang. But the king of the city
state of Yarkand had increased his power by shrewdly
playing off Chinese and Hsiung-nu against each other,
so that before long he was able to attack the Hsiung-nu.
The small states in Turkestan, however, regarded the overlordship of the distant China as preferable to that of Yarkand or the Hsiung-nu both of whom, being nearer, were
able to bring their power more effectively into play. Accordingly many of the
small states appealed for Chinese aid. Kuang-wu Ti
met this appeal with a blank refusal, implying that order had only just been
restored in China and that he now simply had not the resources for a campaign
in Turkestan. Thus, the king of Yarkand was able to
extend his power over the remainder of the small states of Turkestan, since the Hsiung-nu had been obliged to withdraw. Kuang-wu Ti had had several frontier wars with the Hsiung-nu without any decisive result. But in the years
around AD 45 the Hsiung-nu had suffered several
severe droughts and also great plagues of locusts, so that they had lost a
large part of their cattle. They were no longer able to assert themselves in
Turkestan and at the same time to fight the Chinese in the south and the Hsien-pi and the Wu-huan in the
east. These two peoples, apparently largely of Mongol origin, had been subject
in the past to Hsiung-nu overlordship.
They had spread steadily in the territories bordering Manchuria and Mongolia,
beyond the eastern frontier of the Hsiung-nu empire.
Living there in relative peace and at the same time in possession of very
fertile pasturage, these two peoples had grown in strength. And since the great
political collapse of 58 BC the Hsiung-nu had not
only lost their best pasturage in the north of the provinces of Shensi and
Shansi, but had largely grown used to living in co-operation with the Chinese.
They had become much more accustomed to trade with China, exchanging animals
for textiles and grain, than to warfare, so that in the end they were defeated
by the Hsien-pi and Wu-huan,
who had held to the older form of purely war-like nomad life. Weakened by
famine and by the wars against Wu-huan and Hsien-pi, the Hsiung-nu split
into two, one section withdrawing to the north.
The southern Hsiung-nu were
compelled to submit to the Chinese in order to gain security from their other
enemies. Thus the Chinese were able to gain a great success without moving a
finger: the Hsiung-nu, who for centuries had shown
themselves again and again to be the most dangerous enemies of China, were
reduced to political insignificance. About a hundred years earlier the Hsiung-nu empire had suffered defeat; now half of what
remained of it became part of the Chinese state. Its place was taken by the Hsien-pi and Wu-huan, but at
first they were of much less importance.
In spite of the partition, the northern Hsiung-nu attempted in the years between AD 60 and 70 to
regain a sphere of influence in Turkestan; this seemed the easier for them
since the king of Yarkand had been captured and
murdered, and Turkestan was more or less in a state of confusion. The Chinese
did their utmost to play off the northern against the southern Hsiung-nu and to maintain a political balance of power in
the west and north. So long as there were a number of small states in
Turkestan, of which at least some were friendly to China, Chinese trade
caravans suffered relatively little disturbance on their journeys. Independent
states in Turkestan had proved more profitable for trade than when a large army
of occupation had to be maintained there. When, however, there appeared to be
the danger of a new union of the two parts of the Hsiung-nu
as a restoration of a large empire also comprising all Turkestan, the Chinese
trading monopoly was endangered. Any great power would secure the best goods
for itself, and there would be no good business remaining for China.
For these reasons a great Chinese campaign was undertaken
against Turkestan in AD 73 under Tou Ku. Mainly owing
to the ability of the Chinese deputy commander Pan Ch'ao,
the whole of Turkestan was quickly conquered. Meanwhile the emperor Ming Ti (AD
58-75) had died, and under the new emperor Chang Ti (76-88) the
"isolationist" party gained the upper hand against the clique of Tou Ku and Pan Ch'ao: the danger
of the restoration of a Hsiung-nu empire, the isolationists
contended, no longer existed; Turkestan should be left to itself; the small
states would favour trade with China of their own
accord. Meanwhile, a considerable part of Turkestan had fallen away from China,
for Chang Ti sent neither money nor troops to hold the conquered territories.
Pan Ch'ao nevertheless remained in Turkestan (at Kashgar and Khotan) where he held
on amid countless difficulties. Although he reported (AD 78) that the troops
could feed themselves in Turkestan and needed neither supplies nor money from
home, no reinforcements of any importance were sent; only a few hundred or
perhaps a thousand men, mostly released criminals, reached him. Not until AD 89
did the Pan Ch'ao clique return to power when the
mother of the young emperor Ho Ti (89-105) took over the government during his
minority: she was a member of the family of Tou Ku.
She was interested in bringing to a successful conclusion the enterprise which
had been started by members of her family and its followers. In addition, it
can be shown that a number of other members of the "war party" had
direct interests in the west, mainly in form of landed estates. Accordingly, a
campaign was started in 89 under her brother against the northern Hsiung-nu, and it decided the fate of Turkestan in China's
favor. Turkestan remained firmly in Chinese possession until the death of Pan Ch'ao in 102. Shortly afterwards heavy fighting broke out
again: the Tanguts advanced from the south in an
attempt to cut off Chinese access to Turkestan. The Chinese drove back the Tanguts and maintained their hold on Turkestan, though no
longer absolutely.
9.
Economic situation. Rebellion of the "Yellow Turbans".
Collapse of the Han dynasty
The economic results of the Turkestan trade in this
period were not so unfavorable as in the earlier Han period. The army of
occupation was incomparably smaller, and under Pan Ch'ao's policy the soldiers were fed and paid in Turkestan itself, so that the cost to
China remained small. Moreover, the drain on the national income was no longer
serious because, in the intervening period, regular Chinese settlements had
been planted in Turkestan including Chinese merchants, so that the trade no
longer remained entirely in the hands of foreigners.
In spite of the economic consolidation at the
beginning of the Later Han dynasty, and in spite of the more balanced trade,
the political situation within China steadily worsened from AD 80
onwards. Although the class of great landowners was small, a number of cliques
formed within it, and their mutual struggle for power soon went beyond the
limits of court intrigue. New actors now came upon the stage, namely the
eunuchs. With the economic improvement there had been a general increase in the
luxury at the court of the Han emperors, and the court steadily increased in
size. The many hundred wives and concubines in the palace made necessary a
great army of eunuchs. As they had the ear of the emperor and so could
influence him, the eunuchs formed an important political factor. For a time the
main struggle was between the group of eunuchs and the group of scholars. The
eunuchs served a particular clique to which some of the emperor's wives
belonged. The scholars, that is to say the ministers, together with members of
the ministries and the administrative staff, served the interests of another
clique. The struggles grew more and more sanguinary in the middle of the second
century AD. It soon proved that the group with the firmest hold in the
provinces had the advantage, because it was not easy to control the provinces
from a distance. The result was that, from about AD 150, events at court
steadily lost importance, the lead being taken by the generals commanding the
provincial troops. It would carry us too far to give the details of all these
struggles. The provincial generals were at first Ts'ao Ts'ao, Lü Pu, Yüan Shao,
and Sun Ts'ê; later came Liu Pei. All were striving
to gain control of the government, and all were engaged in mutual hostilities
from about 180 onwards. Each general was also trying to get the emperor into
his hands. Several times the last emperor of the Later Han dynasty, Hsien Ti (190-220), was captured by one or another of the
generals. As the successful general was usually unable to maintain his hold on
the capital, he dragged the poor emperor with him from place to place until he
finally had to give him up to another general. The point of this chase after
the emperor was that according to the idea introduced earlier by Wang Mang the first ruler of a new dynasty had to receive the
imperial seals from the last emperor of the previous dynasty. The last emperor
must abdicate in proper form. Accordingly, each general had to get possession
of the emperor to begin with, in order at the proper time to take over the
seals.
By about AD 200 the new conditions had more or less
crystallized. There remained only three great parties. The most powerful was
that of Ts'ao Ts'ao, who
controlled the north and was able to keep permanent hold of the emperor. In the
west, in the province of Szechwan, Liu Pei had established himself, and in the
south-east Sun Ts'ê's brother.
But we must not limit our view to these generals'
struggles. At this time there were two other series of events of equal
importance with those. The incessant struggles of the cliques against each
other continued at the expense of the people, who had to fight them and pay for
them. Thus, after AD 150 the distress of the country population grew beyond all
limits. Conditions were as disastrous as in the time of Wang Mang. And once more, as then, a popular movement broke out,
that of the so-called "Yellow Turbans". This was the first of the two
important events. This popular movement had a characteristic which from now on
became typical of all these risings of the people. The intellectual leaders of
the movement, Chang Ling and others, were members of a particular religious
sect. This sect was influenced by Iranian Mazdaism on
the one side and by certain ideas from Lao Tzŭ;
on the other side; and these influences were superimposed on popular rural as
well as, perhaps, local tribal religious beliefs and superstitions. The sect
had roots along the coastal settlements of Eastern China, where it seems to
have gained the support of the peasantry and their local priests. These priests
of the people were opposed to the representatives of the official religion,
that is to say the officials drawn from the gentry. In small towns and villages
the temples of the gods of the fruits of the field, of the soil, and so on,
were administered by authorized local officials, and these officials also
carried out the prescribed sacrifices. The old temples of the people were
either done away with (we have many edicts of the Han period concerning the
abolition of popular forms of religious worship), or their worship was
converted into an official cult: the all-powerful gentry extended their
domination over religion as well as all else. But the peasants regarded their
local unauthorized priests as their natural leaders against the gentry and
against gentry forms of religion. One branch, probably the main branch of this
movement, developed a stronghold in Eastern Szechwan province, where its
members succeeded to create a state of their own which retained its
independence for a while. It is the only group which developed real religious
communities in which men and women participated, extensive welfare schemes
existed and class differences were discouraged. It had a real church
organization with dioceses, communal friendship meals and a confession ritual;
in short, real piety developed as it could not develop in the official
religions. After the annihilation of this state, remnants of the organization
can be traced through several centuries, mainly in central and south China. It
may well be that the many "Taoistic" traits
which can be found in the religions of late and present-day Mongolian and
Tibetan tribes, can be derived from this movement of the Yellow Turbans.
The rising of the Yellow Turbans began in 184; all
parties, cliques and generals alike, were equally afraid of the
revolutionaries, since these were a threat to the gentry as such, and so to all
parties. Consequently a combined army of considerable size was got together and
sent against the rebels. The Yellow Turbans were beaten.
During these struggles it became evident that Ts'ao Ts'ao with his troops had
become the strongest of all the generals. His troops seem to have consisted not
of Chinese soldiers alone, but also of Hsiung-nu. It
is understandable that the annals say nothing about this, and it can only be
inferred from the facts. It appears that in order to reinforce their armies the
generals recruited not only Chinese but foreigners. The generals operating in
the region of the present-day Peking had soldiers of the Wu-huan and Hsien-pi, and even of the Ting-ling; Liu Pei, in
the west, made use of Tanguts, and Ts'ao Ts'ao clearly went farthest
of all in this direction; he seems to have been responsible for settling
nineteen tribes of Hsiung-nu in the Chinese province
of Shansi between 180 and 200, in return for their armed aid. In this way Ts'ao Ts'ao gained permanent
power in the empire by means of these troops, so that immediately after his
death his son Ts'ao P'ei,
with the support of powerful allied families, was able to force the emperor to
abdicate and to found a new dynasty, the Wei dynasty (AD 220).
This meant, however, that a part of China which for
several centuries had been Chinese was given up to the Hsiung-nu.
This was not, of course, what Ts'ao Ts'ao had intended; he had given the Hsiung-nu
some area of pasturage in Shansi with the idea that they should be controlled
and administered by the officials of the surrounding district. His plan had
been similar to what the Chinese had often done with success: aliens were
admitted into the territory of the empire in a body, but then the influence of
the surrounding administrative centres was steadily
extended over them, until the immigrants completely lost their own nationality
and became Chinese. The nineteen tribes of Hsiung-nu,
however, were much too numerous, and after the prolonged struggles in China the
provincial administration proved much too weak to be able to carry out the
plan. Thus there came into existence here, within China, a small Hsiung-nu realm ruled by several shan-yü. This was the second major development, and it
became of the utmost importance to the history of the next four centuries.
10.
Literature
and Art
With the development of the new class of the gentry in
the Han period, there was an increase in the number of those who were anxious
to participate in what had been in the past an exclusively aristocratic
possession—education. Thus it is by no mere chance that in this period many encyclopaedias were compiled. Encyclopaedias convey knowledge in an easily grasped and easily found form. The first
compilation of this sort dates from the third century BC. It was the work of Lü Pu-wei, the merchant who was
prime minister and regent during the minority of Shih Huang-ti.
It contains general information concerning ceremonies, customs, historic
events, and other things the knowledge of which was part of a general
education. Soon afterwards other encyclopaedias appeared, of which the best known is the Book of the Mountains and Seas (Shan Hai Ching). This book, arranged
according to regions of the world, contains everything known at the time about
geography, natural philosophy, and the animal and plant world, and also about
popular myths. This tendency to systemization is shown also in the historical
works. The famous Shih Chi, one of our main sources for Chinese history, is the
first historical work of the modern type, that is to say, built up on a
definite plan, and it was also the model for all later official historiography.
Its author, Ssŭ-ma Ch'ien (born 135 BC), and his father, made use of the material in the state archives
and of private documents, old historical and philosophical books, inscriptions,
and the results of their own travels. The philosophical and historical books of
earlier times (with the exception of those of the nature of chronicles)
consisted merely of a few dicta or reports of particular events, but the Shih
Chi is a compendium of a mass of source-material. The documents were
abbreviated, but the text of the extracts was altered as little as possible, so
that the general result retains in a sense the value of an original source. In
its arrangement the Shih Chi became a model for all later historians: the first
part is in the form of annals, and there follow tables concerning the occupants
of official posts and fiefs, and then biographies of various important
personalities, though the type of the comprehensive biography did not appear
till later. The Shih Chi also, like later historical works, contains many
monographs dealing with particular fields of knowledge, such as astronomy, the
calendar, music, economics, official dress at court, and much else. The whole
type of construction differs fundamentally from such works as those of
Thucydides or Herodotus. The Chinese historical works have the advantage that
the section of annals gives at once the events of a particular year, the
monographs describe the development of a particular field of knowledge, and the
biographical section offers information concerning particular personalities.
The mental attitude is that of the gentry: shortly after the time of Ssŭ-ma Ch'ien an historical
department was founded, in which members of the gentry worked as historians
upon the documents prepared by representatives of the gentry in the various government
offices.
In addition to encyclopaedias and historical works, many books of philosophy were written in the Han period,
but most of them offer no fundamentally new ideas. They were the product of the
leisure of rich members of the gentry, and only three of them are of
importance. One is the work of Tung Chung-shu,
already mentioned. The second is a book by Liu An called Huai-nan Tzŭ. Prince Liu An occupied himself with Taoism
and allied problems, gathered around him scholars of different schools, and
carried on discussions with them. Many of his writings are lost, but enough is
extant to show that he was one of the earliest Chinese alchemists. The question
has not yet been settled, but it is probable that alchemy first appeared in
China, together with the cult of the "art" of prolonging life, and
was later carried to the West, where it flourished among the Arabs and in
medieval Europe.
The third important book of the Han period was the Lun Hêng (Critique of Opinions)
of Wang Ch'ung, which appeared in the first century
of the Christian era. Wang Ch'ung advocated rational
thinking and tried to pave the way for a free natural science, in continuation
of the beginnings which the natural philosophers of the later Chou period had made.
The book analyses reports in ancient literature and customs of daily life, and
shows how much they were influenced by superstition and by ignorance of the
facts of nature. From this attitude a modern science might have developed, as
in Europe towards the end of the Middle Ages; but the gentry had every reason
to play down this tendency which, with its criticism of all that was
traditional, might have proceeded to an attack on the dominance of the gentry
and their oppression especially of the merchants and artisans. It is
fascinating to observe how it was the needs of the merchants and seafarers of
Asia Minor and Greece that provided the stimulus for the growth of the classic
sciences, and how on the contrary the growth of Chinese science was stifled because
the gentry were so strongly hostile to commerce and navigation, though both had
always existed.
There were great literary innovations in the field of
poetry. The splendor and elegance at the new imperial court of the Han dynasty
attracted many poets who sang the praises of the emperor and his court and were
given official posts and dignities. These praises were in the form of
grandiloquent, overloaded poetry, full of strange similes and allusions, but
with little real feeling. In contrast, the many women singers and dancers at
the court, mostly slaves from southern China, introduced at the court southern
Chinese forms of song and poem, which were soon adopted and elaborated by
poets. Poems and dance songs were composed which belonged to the finest that
Chinese poetry can show—full of natural feeling, simple in language, moving in
content.
Our knowledge of the arts is drawn from two
sources—literature, and the actual discoveries in the excavations. Thus we know
that most of the painting was done on silk, of which plenty came into the
market through the control of silk-producing southern China. Paper had
meanwhile been invented in the second century BC, by perfecting the techniques
of making bark-cloth and felt. Unfortunately nothing remains of the actual
works that were the first examples of what the Chinese everywhere were
beginning to call "art". "People", that is to say the
gentry, painted as a social pastime, just as they assembled together for
poetry, discussion, or performances of song and dance; they painted as an
aesthetic pleasure and rarely as a means of earning. We find philosophic ideas
or greetings, emotions, and experiences represented by paintings—paintings with
fanciful or ideal landscapes; paintings representing life and environment of
the cultured class in idealized form, never naturalistic either in fact or in
intention. Until recently it was an indispensable condition in the Chinese view
that an artist must be "cultured" and be a member of the
gentry—distinguished, unoccupied, wealthy. A man who was paid for his work, for
instance for a portrait for the ancestral cult, was until late time regarded as
a craftsman, not as an artist. Yet, these "craftsmen" have produced
in Han time and even earlier, many works which, in our view, undoubtedly belong
to the realm of art. In the tombs have been found reliefs whose technique is
generally intermediate between simple outline engraving and intaglio. The
lining-in is most frequently executed in scratched lines. The representations,
mostly in strips placed one above another, are of lively historical scenes,
scenes from the life of the dead, great ritual ceremonies, or adventurous
scenes from mythology. Bronze vessels have representations in inlaid gold and
silver, mostly of animals. The most important documents of the painting of the
Han period have also been found in tombs. We see especially ladies and
gentlemen of society, with richly ornamented, elegant, expensive clothing that
is very reminiscent of the clothing customary to this day in Japan. There are
also artistic representations of human figures on lacquer caskets. While
sculpture was not strongly developed, the architecture of the Han must have
been magnificent and technically highly complex. Sculpture and temple
architecture received a great stimulus with the spread of Buddhism in China.
According to our present knowledge, Buddhism entered China from the south coast
and through Central Asia at latest in the first century BC; it came with
foreign merchants from India or Central Asia. According to Indian customs,
Brahmans, the Hindu caste providing all Hindu priests, could not leave their
homes. As merchants on their trips which lasted often several years, did not
want to go without religious services, they turned to Buddhist priests as well
as to priests of Near Eastern religions. These priests were not prevented from
travelling and used this opportunity for missionary purposes. Thus, for a long
time after the first arrival of Buddhists, the Buddhist priests in China were
foreigners who served foreign merchant colonies. The depressed conditions of
the people in the second century AD drove members of the lower classes into
their arms, while the parts of Indian science which these priests brought with
them from India aroused some interest in certain educated circles. Buddhism,
therefore, undeniably exercised an influence at the end of the Han dynasty,
although no Chinese were priests and few, if any, gentry members were adherents
of the religious teachings.
With the end of the Han period a further epoch of
Chinese history comes to its close. The Han period was that of the final
completion and consolidation of the social order of the gentry. The period that
followed was that of the conflicts of the Chinese with the populations on their
northern borders.
CHAPTER VII.THE EPOCH OF THE FIRST DIVISION OF CHINA(A.D.220-580)
|