READING HALLDOORS OF WISDOM |
BISMARCKAND THE FOUNDATION OF THE GERMAN EMPIRE1815-1898CHAPTER XVI.THE TRIPLE ALLIANCE AND ECONOMIC REFORM.1878-1887.
The year 1878 forms
a turning-point both in internal and in external politics. Up to this year
Prussia has been allied with the two Eastern monarchies; the Empire has been
governed by the help of the National Liberal party; the chief enemy has been
the Clericals. The traditions of the time before the war are still maintained.
After this year the understanding with Russia breaks down; instead of it the
peace of Europe is preserved by the Triple Alliance with Austria and Italy. In
internal affairs the change is even more marked; the rising power of the
Socialists is the enemy to be fought against; for this conflict, peace has to be made with the Catholics—the May laws are modified
or repealed. The alliance with Liberalism breaks down, and the efforts of the
Government are devoted to a far-reaching scheme of financial reform and social
legislation.
When, in April, 1877, the Emperor refused to accept Bismarck's
resignation, the whole country applauded the decision. In the Reichstag a great
demonstration was made of confidence in the Chancellor. Everyone felt that he
could not be spared at a time when the complications in the East were bringing
new dangers upon Europe, and in the seclusion of Varzin he did not cease during the next months to direct the foreign policy of the
Empire. He was able with the other Governments of Europe to prevent the spread
of hostilities from Turkey to the rest of Europe, and when the next year the
English Government refused its assent to the provisional peace of San Stefano,
it was the unanimous desire of all the other States that the settlement of
Turkey should be submitted to a Congress at Berlin over which he should
preside. It was the culmination of his public career; it was the recognition by
Europe in the most impressive way of his primacy among living statesmen. In his
management of the Congress he answered to the
expectations formed of him. "We do not wish to go," he had said,
"the way of Napoleon; we do not desire to be the arbitrators or
schoolmasters of Europe. We do not wish to force our policy on other States by
appealing to the strength of our army. I look on our task as a more useful
though a humbler one; it is enough if we can be an honest broker." He
succeeded in the task he had set before himself, and in reconciling the
apparently incompatible desires of England and Russia. Again and again when the Congress seemed about to break up without result he made
himself the spokesman of Russian wishes, and conveyed them to Lord Beaconsfield,
the English plenipotentiary.
None the less the
friendship of Russia, which had before wavered, now broke down. A bitter attack
on Germany and Bismarck was begun in the Russian Press; the new German fiscal
policy led to misunderstandings; the Czar in private letters to the Emperor demanded in the negotiations that were still going
on the absolute and unconditional support of Germany to all Russian demands as
the condition of Russian friendship. In the autumn of the next year matters
came near to war; it was in these circumstances that Bismarck brought about
that alliance which ever since then has governed European politics. He hastily
arranged a meeting with Count Andrassy, the Austrian Minister, and in a few
days the two statesmen agreed on a defensive alliance between the two Empires. Many
years later, in 1886, the instrument of alliance was published. It was agreed
that if either of the German States was attacked by Russia the other would join
to defend it; if either was attacked by France the other would observe
neutrality; but if the French were supported by Russia then the first clause would come into force. The Emperor of Austria willingly
gave his assent; it was only after a prolonged struggle that Bismarck was able
to gain the assent of his own sovereign. This alliance, which in the next year
was joined by Italy, again gave Germany the ruling position in Europe.
During this crisis
in foreign affairs Bismarck was occupied by another, which threatened to be
equally serious, in home politics. In the spring of 1878 an attempt was made on the life of the
Emperor; a young man, named Hobel, a shoemaker's
apprentice, shot at him in the streets of Berlin, fortunately without result.
The attempt naturally created intense indignation throughout the country. This
was increased when it became known that he had been to some extent connected
with the Socialist party, and it seemed as though the motives of the crime were
supplied by the violent speeches made at Socialist gatherings. Bismarck had
long regarded the growth of Socialism with concern. He determined to use this
opportunity to crush it. He at once brought into the Bundesrath a very severe law, forbidding all Socialist agitation and propaganda. He
succeeded in passing it through the Council, but it was thrown out in the
Reichstag by a very large majority. No one voted for it except the
Conservatives. The law indeed was so drawn up that one does not see how anyone
could have voted for it; the first clause began, "Printed writings and
unions which follow the aims of Social Democracy may be forbidden by the
Federal Council," but, as was pointed out, among the aims of Social
Democracy were many which were good in themselves, and many others which,
though they might be considered harmful by other parties, were at least
legitimate. Directly afterwards the Reichstag was prorogued. Ten days later,
another attempt was made on the Emperor's life; this
time a man of the name of Nobeling (an educated man
who had studied at the University) shot at him while driving in the Unter den Linden, and wounded him severely in the head and
arms with large shot. The Emperor was driven home to
his palace almost unconscious, and for some time his life was in danger. This
second attempt in so short a time on the life of a man almost eighty years of
age, so universally loved and respected, who had conferred such benefits on his
country, naturally aroused a storm of indignation. When Bismarck received the
news his first words were, "Now the Reichstag must be dissolved."
This was done; the general elections took place while the excitement was still
hot, and of course resulted in a great loss to those parties—especially the
National Liberals—who had voted against the Socialist law; the Centre alone
retained its numbers. Before this new Parliament a fresh law was laid, drafted with
much more skill. It absolutely forbade all speeches or writing in favour of
plans for overthrowing the order of society, or directed against marriage and property. It enabled the Government to proclaim
in all large towns a state of siege, and to expel from them by the mere decree
of the police anyone suspected of Socialist agitation. The law, which was
easily carried, was enforced with great severity; a state of siege was
proclaimed in Berlin and many other places. Socialist papers, and even books, for
instance the writings of Lassalle, were forbidden; they might not even be read
in public libraries; and for the next twelve years the Socialist party had to
carry on their propaganda by secret means.
This Socialist law
is very disappointing; we find the Government again having recourse to the same
means for checking and guiding opinion which Metternich had used fifty years
before. Not indeed that the Socialists themselves had any ground for complaint;
their avowed end was the overthrow of government and society; they professed to
be at war with all established institutions; if they confined their efforts to
legal measures and did not use violence, it was only because the time had not
yet come. The men who avowed admiration for the Paris Commune, who were openly
preparing for a revolution more complete than any which Europe had hitherto
seen, could not complain if the Government, while there was yet time, used
every means for crushing them. The mistake was in supposing that this measure
would be successful. Bismarck would, indeed, had he been able, have made it far
more severe; his own idea was that anyone who had been legally convicted of
holding Socialist opinions should be deprived of the franchise and excluded
from the Parliament. What a misunderstanding does this shew of the whole object
and nature of representative institutions! It had been decided that in Germany
Parliament was not to govern; what then was its function except to display the
opinions of the people? If, as was the case, so large a proportion of the
German nation belonged to a party of discontent, then it was above all
desirable that their wishes and desires should have open expression,
and be discussed where they could be overthrown. The Government had
enormous means of influencing opinion. In the old days the men of letters had
been on principle in opposition; now Germany was flooded by papers, books, and
pamphlets; all devoted to the most extravagant praise of the new institutions.
The excuse which was made for these laws was not a sufficient one. It is seldom
necessary to meet political assassination by repressive measures, for they must
always create a danger which they intend to avert. There was not the slightest
ground for supposing that either Hobel or Nobeling had any confederates; there was no plot; it was
but the wild and wicked action of an individual. It was as absurd to put a
large party under police control for this reason as it was to punish Liberals
for the action of Sand. And it was ineffective, as the events of the next years
showed; for the Socialist law did not spare Germany from the infection of
outrage which in these years overran Europe.
The Socialist laws
were soon followed by other proposals of a more useful kind, and now we come to
one of the most remarkable episodes in Bismarck's career. He was over sixty
years of age; his health was uncertain; he had long complained of the extreme
toil and the constant annoyance which his public duties brought upon him. It
might appear that he had finished his work, and, if he could not retire
altogether, would give over the management of all internal affairs to others.
That he would now take upon himself a whole new department of public duties,
that he would after his prolonged absence appear again as leader and innovator
in Parliamentary strife—this no one anticipated.
Up to the year 1876
he had taken little active part in finance; his energies had been entirely
absorbed by foreign affairs and he had been content to adopt and support the
measures recommended by his technical advisers. When he had interfered at all
it had only been on those occasions when, as with regard to commercial treaties, the policy of his colleagues had impeded his own political
objects. In 1864 he had been much annoyed because difference on commercial
matters had interfered with the good understanding with Austria, which at that
time he was trying to maintain. Since the foundation of the Empire almost the
complete control over the commercial policy of the Empire had been entrusted to
Delbrück, who held the very important post of President of the Imperial Chancery, and was treated by Bismarck with a deference and
consideration which no other of his fellow-workers received, except Moltke and Roon. Delbrück was a confirmed Free-Trader, and the result
was that, partly by commercial treaties, and partly by the abolition of customs
dues, the tariff had been reduced and simplified. The years following the war
had, however, not been altogether prosperous; a great outbreak of speculation
was followed in 1873 by a serious commercial crisis. And since that year there
had been a permanent decrease in the Imperial receipts. This was, for political
reasons, a serious inconvenience. By the arrangement made in 1866 the proceeds
of the customs and of the indirect taxation (with some exceptions) were paid
into the Exchequer of the Federation, and afterwards of the Empire. If the
receipts from these sources were not sufficient to meet the Imperial
requirements, the deficit had to be made up by contributions paid (in
proportion to their population) by the separate States. During later years
these contributions had annually increased, and it is needless to point out
that this was sufficient to make the relations of the State Governments to the
central authorities disagreeable, and to cause some discontent with the new
Constitution. This meant also an increase of the
amount which had to be raised by direct taxation. Now Bismarck had always much
disliked direct taxes; he had again and again pointed out that they were paid
with great reluctance, and often fell with peculiar hardship on that very large
class which could only just, by constant and assiduous labour,
make an income sufficient for their needs. Worst of all was it when they were
unable to pay even the few shillings required; they then had to undergo the
hardship and disgrace of distraint, and see their furniture seized and sold by
the tax-collectors. He had therefore always wished that the income derived from
customs and indirect taxation should be increased so as by degrees to do away
with the necessity for direct taxation, and if this could be done, then,
instead of the States paying an annual contribution to the Empire, they would
receive from the central Government pecuniary assistance.
The dislike of
direct taxation is an essential part of Bismarck's reform; he especially
disapproved of the Prussian system, the barbarous system, as he called it,
according to which every man had to pay a small portion, it might be even a few
groschen, in direct taxes.
"I
ascribe," he said, "the large part of our emigration to the fact that
the emigrant wishes to escape the direct pressure of the taxes and execution,
and to go to a land where the klassensteuer does not
exist, and where he will also have the pleasure of knowing that the produce of
his labours will be protected against foreign
interference."
His opinion cannot
be called exaggerated if it is true that, as he stated, there were every year
over a million executions involving the seizure and sale of household goods on
account of arrears of taxation. It was not only the State taxes to which he
objected; the local rates for municipal expenses, and especially for education,
fell very heavily on the inhabitants of large cities such as Berlin. He
intended to devote part of the money which was raised by indirect taxation to
relieving the rates.
His first proposals
for raising the money were of a very sweeping nature. He wished to introduce a State monopoly for the sale of tobacco, brandy, and beer. He entered into calculations by which he proved that were
his policy adopted all direct taxation might be repealed, and he would have a
large surplus for an object which he had very much at heart—the provision of
old-age pensions. It was a method of legislation copied from that which
prevails in France and Italy. He pointed out with perfect justice that the
revenue raised in Germany from the consumption of tobacco was much smaller than
it ought to be. The total sum gained by the State was not a tenth of that which
was produced in England by the taxing of tobacco, but no one could maintain
that smoking was more common in England than in Germany. In fact tobacco was less heavily taxed in Germany than in any other country in Europe.
In introducing a
monopoly Bismarck intended and hoped not only to relieve the pressure of direct taxation,—though this would have been a change
sufficient in its magnitude and importance for most men,—but proposed to use
the very large sum which the Government would have at its disposal for the
direct relief of the working classes. The Socialist law was not to go alone; he
intended absolutely to stamp out this obnoxious agitation, but it was not from
any indifference as to the condition of the working classes. From his earliest
days he had been opposed to the Liberal doctrine of laissez-faire; it will be
remembered how much he had disliked the bourgeois domination of the July Monarchy; as a young man he had tried to prevent the
abolition of guilds. He considered that much of the distress and discontent
arose from the unrestricted influence of capital. He was only acting in
accordance with the oldest and best traditions of the Prussian Monarchy when he
called in the power of the State to protect the poor. His plan was a very bold
one; he wished to institute a fund from which there should be paid to every
working man who was incapacitated by sickness, accident, or old age, a pension
from the State. In his original plan he intended the working men should not be
required to make any contribution themselves towards this fund. It was not to
be made to appear to them as a new burden imposed on them by the State. The
tobacco monopoly, he said, he looked on as "the patrimony of the
disinherited."
He did not fear the
charge of Socialism which might be brought against him; he defended himself by
the provisions of the Prussian law. The Code of Frederick the Great contained
the words:
"It is the
duty of the State to provide for the sustenance and support of those of its
citizens who cannot procure sustenance themselves"; and again, "work
adapted to their strength and capacity shall be supplied to those who lack
means and opportunity of earning a livelihood for themselves and those
dependent on them."
In the most public way the new policy was introduced by an Imperial message, on
November 17, 1881, in which the Emperor expressed his conviction that the
social difficulties could not be healed simply by the repression of the
exaggerations of Social Democracy, but at the same time the welfare of the
workmen must be advanced. This new policy had the warm approval of both the
Emperor and the Crown Prince; no one greeted more heartily the change than
Windthorst.
"Allow
me," he once said to Bismarck, "to speak openly: you have done me
much evil in my life, but, as a German patriot, I must confess to you my
gratitude that after all his political deeds you have persuaded our Imperial
Master to turn to this path of Social Reform."
There were, he
said, difficulties to be met; he approved of the end, but not of all the
details, "and," he continued,
"something of the difficulty, if I may say so, you cause yourself. You are
often too stormy for us; you are always coming with something new and we cannot always follow you in it, but you must not
take that amiss. We are both old men and the Emperor is much older than we are, but we should like ourselves in our lifetime to see
some of these reforms established. That I wish for all of us and for our German
country, and we will do our best to help in it."
Opinions may differ
as to the wisdom of Bismarck's social and financial policy; nobody can deny
their admiration for the energy and patriotism which he displayed. It was no
small thing for him, at his age, to come out of his comparative retirement to
bring forward proposals which would be sure to excite the bitterest opposition
of the men with whom he had been working, to embark again on a Parliamentary
conflict as keen as any of those which had so taxed his energies in his younger
years. Not content with inaugurating and suggesting these plans, he himself
undertook the immediate execution of them. In addition to his other offices, in
1880 he undertook that of Minister of Trade in Prussia, for he found no one
whom he could entirely trust to carry out his proposals. During the next years
he again took a prominent part in the Parliamentary debates; day after day he
attended to answer objections and to defend his measures in some of his ablest and
longest speeches. By his proposals for a duty on corn he regained the support
of most of the Conservatives, but in the Reichstag which was elected in 1884 he
found himself opposed by a majority consisting of the Centre, Socialists, and
Progressives. Many of the laws were rejected or amended, and it was not until
1890 that, in a modified form, the whole of the social legislation had been
carried through.
For the monopoly he
gained no support; scarcely a voice was raised in its favour, nor can we be
surprised at this. It was a proposal very characteristic of his internal
policy; he had a definite aim in view and at once took the shortest, boldest,
and most direct road towards it, putting aside the thought of all further
consequences. In this others could not follow him;
quite apart from the difficulties of organisation and
the unknown effect of the law on all those who gained their livelihood by the
growth, preparation, and sale of tobacco, there was a deep feeling that it was
not safe to entrust the Government with so enormous a power. Men did not wish
to see so many thousands enrolled in the army of officials, already too great;
they did not desire a new check on the freedom of life and occupation, nor that
the Government should have the uncontrolled use of so great a sum of money. And
then the use he proposed to make of the proceeds: if the calculations were
correct, if the results were what he foretold, if from this monopoly they would
be able to pay not only the chief expenses of the Government but also assign an
old-age pension to every German workman who reached the age of seventy—what
would this be except to make the great majority of the nation prospective
pensioners of the State? With compulsory attendance at the State schools; with
the State universities as the only entrance to public life and professions;
when everyone for three years had to serve in the army; when so large a
proportion of the population earned their livelihood in the railways, the
post-office, the customs, the administration—the State had already a power and
influence which many besides the Liberals regarded with alarm. What would it be
when every working man looked forward to receiving, after his working days were
over, a free gift from the Government? Could not this
power be used for political measures also; could not it become a means for
checking the freedom of opinions and even for interfering in the liberty of
voting?
He had to raise the
money he wanted in another way, and, in 1879, he began the great financial
change that he had been meditating for three years; he threw all his vigour into overthrowing Free Trade and introducing a
general system of Protection.
In this he was only
doing what a large number of his countrymen desired.
The results of Free Trade had not been satisfactory. In 1876 there was a great
crisis in the iron trade; owing to overproduction there was a great fall of
prices in England, and Germany was being flooded with English goods sold below
cost price. Many factories had to be closed, owners were ruined, and men thrown
out of work; it happened that, by a law passed in 1873, the last duty on
imported iron would cease on the 31st of December, 1876. Many of the manufacturers and a large party in the Reichstag petitioned
that the action of the law might at any rate be suspended. Free-Traders,
however, still had a majority, for the greater portion of the National Liberals
belonged to that school, and the law was carried out. It was, however, apparent
that not only the iron but other industries were threatened. The building of
railways in Russia would bring about an increased importation of Russian corn
and threatened the prosperity, not only of the large proprietors, but also of
the peasants. It had always been the wise policy of the Prussian Government to
maintain and protect by legislation the peasants, who were considered the most
important class in the State. Then the trade in Swedish wood threatened to
interfere with the profits from the German forests, an industry so useful to
the health of the country and the prosperity of the Government. But if Free
Trade would injure the market for the natural products of the soil, it did not
bring any compensating advantages by helping industry. Germany was flooded with
English manufactures, so that even the home market was endangered, and every
year it became more apparent that foreign markets were being closed. The
sanguine expectations of the Free-Traders had not been realised;
America, France, Russia, had high tariffs; German manufactured goods were
excluded from these countries. What could they look forward to in the future
but a ruined peasantry and the crippling of the iron and weaving industries?
"I had the impression," said Bismarck, "that under Free Trade we
were gradually bleeding to death."
He was probably
much influenced in his new policy by Lothar Bucher, one of his private
secretaries, who was constantly with him at Varzin.
Bucher, who had been an extreme Radical, had, in 1849, been compelled to fly
from the country and had lived many years in England. In 1865 he had entered
Bismarck's service. He had acquired a peculiar enmity to the Cobden Club, and looked on that institution as the subtle
instrument of a deep-laid plot to persuade other nations to adopt a policy
which was entirely for the benefit of England. He drew attention to Cobden's
words—"All we desire is the prosperity and greatness of England." We
may in fact look on the Cobden Club and the principles it advocated from two
points of view. Either they are, as Bucher maintained, simply English and their
only result will be the prosperity of England, or they are merely one
expression of a general form of thought which we know as Liberalism; it was an
attempt to create cosmopolitan institutions and to induce German politicians to
take their economic doctrines from England, just as a few years before they had
taken their political theories. In either case these doctrines would be very
distasteful to Bismarck, who disliked internationalism in finance as much as he
did in constitutional law or Socialist propaganda.
Bismarck in
adopting Protection was influenced, not by economic theory, but by the
observation of facts. "All nations," he said, "which have
Protective duties enjoy a certain prosperity; what great advantages has America
reached since it threatened to reduce duties twice, five times, ten times as
high as ours!" England alone clung to Free Trade, and why? Because she had
grown so strong under the old system of Protection that she could now as a
Hercules step down into the arena and challenge everyone to come into the
lists. In the arena of commerce England was the strongest. This was why she
advocated Free Trade, for Free Trade was really the right of the most powerful.
English interests were furthered under the veil of the magic word Freedom, and
by it German enthusiasts for liberty were enticed to
bring about the ruin and exploitation of their own country.
If we look at the
matter purely from the economic point of view, it is indeed difficult to see
what benefits Germany would gain from a policy of Free Trade. It was a poor
country; if it was to maintain itself in the modern rivalry of nations, it must
become rich. It could only become rich through manufactures,
and manufactures had no opportunity of growing unless they had some
moderate protection from foreign competition.
The effect of
Bismarck's attention to finance was not limited to these great reforms; he
directed the whole power of the Government to the support of all forms of
commercial enterprise and to the removal of all hindrances to the prosperity of
the nation. To this task he devoted himself with the same courage and
determination which he had formerly shewn in his diplomatic work.
One essential
element in the commercial reform was the improvement of the railways.
Bismarck's attention had long been directed to the inconveniences which arose
from the number of private companies, whose duty it was to regard the dividends
of the shareholders rather than the interests of the public. The existence of a
monopoly of this kind in private hands seemed to him indefensible. His
attention was especially directed to the injury done to trade by the
differential rate imposed on goods traffic; on many lines it was the custom to
charge lower rates on imported than on exported goods, and this naturally had a
very bad effect on German manufactures. He would have liked to remedy all these
deficiencies by making all railways the property of the Empire (we see again
his masterful mind, which dislikes all compromise); in this, however, he was
prevented by the opposition of the other States, who would not surrender the
control of their own lines. In Prussia he was able to carry out this policy of
purchase of all private lines by the State; by the time he laid down the
Ministry of Commerce hardly any private companies remained. The acquisition of
all the lines enabled the Government greatly to improve the communication, to
lower fares, and to introduce through communications; all this of course
greatly added to the commercial enterprise and therefore the wealth of the
country.
He was now also
able to give degrees his encouragement and support to those Germans who for
many years in countries beyond the sea had been attempting to lay the
foundations for German commerce and even to acquire German colonies. Bismarck's
attitude in this matter deserves careful attention. As early as 1874 he had
been approached by German travellers to ask for the
support of the Government in a plan for acquiring German colonies in South
Africa. They pointed out that here was a country fitted by its climate for
European occupation; the present inhabitants of a large portion of it, the
Boers, were anxious to establish their independence of England and would
welcome German support. It was only necessary to acquire a port, either at
Santa Lucia or at Delagoa Bay, to receive a small subsidy from the Government,
and then private enterprise would divert the stream of German emigration from
North America to South Africa. Bismarck, though he gave a courteous hearing to
this proposal, could not promise them assistance, for, as he said, the
political situation was not favourable. He must
foresee that an attempt to carry out this or similar plans would inevitably
bring about very serious difficulties with England, and he had always been
accustomed to attach much importance to his good understanding with the English
Government. During the following years, however, the situation was much
altered. First of all, great enterprise had been shewn
by the German merchants and adventurers in different parts of the world,
especially in Africa and in the Pacific. They, in those difficulties which will
always occur when white traders settle in half-civilised lands, applied for support to the German Government. Bismarck, as he himself
said, did not dare to refuse them this support.
"I approached
the matter with some reluctance; I asked myself, how could I justify it, if I
said to these enterprising men, over whose courage, enthusiasm, and vigour I have been heartily pleased: 'That is all very
well, but the German Empire is not strong enough, it would attract the ill-will
of other States.' I had not the courage as Chancellor to declare to them this
bankruptcy of the German nation for transmarine enterprises."
It must, however,
happen that wherever these German settlers went, they would be in the neighbourhood of some English colony, and however friendly
were the relations of the Governments of the two Powers, disputes must occur in
the outlying p arts of the earth. In the first years of the Empire Bismarck had
hoped that German traders would find sufficient protection from the English authorities, and anticipated their taking advantage of the
full freedom of trade allowed in the British colonies; they would get all the
advantages which would arise from establishing their own colonies, while the
Government would be spared any additional responsibility. He professed,
however, to have learnt by experience from the difficulties which came after
the annexation of the Fiji Islands by Great Britain that this hope would not be
fulfilled; he acknowledged the great friendliness of the Foreign Office, but complained that the Colonial Office regarded
exclusively British interests. As a complaint coming from his mouth this
arouses some amusement; the Colonial Office expressed itself satisfied to have
received from so high an authority a testimonial to its efficiency which it had
rarely gained from Englishmen.
The real change in
the policy of the Empire must, however, be attributed not to any imaginary
shortcomings of the English authorities; it was an inevitable result of the
abandonment of the policy of Free Trade, and of the active support which the
Government was now giving to all forms of commercial enterprise. It was shewn, first of all, in the grant of subsidies to mail steamers,
which enabled German trade and German travellers henceforward to be carried by German ships; before they had depended entirely on
English and French lines. It was not till 1884 that the Government saw its way
to undertake protection of German colonists. They were enabled to do so by the
great change which had taken place in the political situation. Up to this time
Germany was powerless to help or to injure England, but, on the other hand,
required English support. All this was changed by the occupation of Egypt. Here
England required a support on the Continent against the indignation of France
and the jealousy of Russia. This could only be found in Germany, and therefore
a close approximation between the two countries was natural. Bismarck let it be
known that England would find no support, but rather opposition, if she, on her
side, attempted, as she so easily could have done, to impede German colonial
enterprise.
In his colonial
policy Bismarck refused to take the initiative; he refused, also, to undertake
the direct responsibility for the government of their new possessions. He
imitated the older English plan, and left the government
in the hands of private companies, who received a charter of incorporation; he
avowedly was imitating the East India Company and the Hudson's Bay Company. The
responsibilities of the German Government were limited to a protection of the
companies against the attack or interference by any other Power, and a general
control over their actions. In this way it was possible to avoid calling on the
Reichstag for any large sum, or undertaking the responsibility of an extensive
colonial establishment, for which at the time they had neither men nor
experience. Another reason against the direct annexation of foreign countries
lay in the Constitution of the Empire; it would have been easier to annex fresh
land to Prussia; this could have been done by the authority of the King; there
was, however, no provision by which the Bundesrath could undertake this responsibility, and it probably could not be done even
with the assent of the Reichstag unless some change were made in the Constitution. It was, however, essential that the new
acquisitions should be German and not Prussian.
All these changes
were not introduced without much opposition; the Progressives especially
distinguished themselves by their prolonged refusal to assent even to the
subsidies for German lines of steamers. In the Parliament of
1884 they were enabled often to throw out the Government proposals. It
was at this time that the conflict between Bismarck and Richter reached its
height. He complained, and justly complained, that the policy of the Progressives
was then, as always, negative. It is indeed strange to notice how we find
reproduced in Germany that same feeling which a few years before had in England
nearly led to the loss of the colonies and the destruction of the Empire.
It is too soon even
now to consider fully the result of this new policy; the introduction of
Protection has indeed, if we are to judge by appearances, brought about a great
increase in the prosperity of the country; whether the scheme for old-age
pensions will appease the discontent of the working man seems very doubtful.
One thing, however, we must notice: the influence of the new policy is far
greater than the immediate results of the actual laws passed. It has taught the
Germans to look to the Government not only as a means of protecting them
against the attacks of other States, but to see in it a thoughtful, and I think
we may say kindly, guardian of their interests. They know that every attempt of each individual to gain wealth or power for his
country will be supported and protected by the Government; they know that there
is constant watchfulness as to the dangers to life and health which arise from
the conditions of modern civilisation. In these laws,
in fact, Bismarck, who deeply offended and irretrievably alienated the survivors
of his own generation, won over and secured for himself and
also for the Government the complete loyalty of the rising generation.
It might be supposed that this powerful action on the part of the State would
interfere with private enterprise; the result shews that this is not the case.
A watchful and provident Government really acts as an incentive to each individual. Let us also recognise that Bismarck was acting exactly as in the old days every English Government
acted, when the foreign policy was dictated by the interests of British trade
and the home policy aimed at preserving, protecting, and assisting the
different classes in the community.
Bismarck has often
been called a reactionary, and yet we find that by the social legislation he
was the first statesman deliberately to apply himself to the problem which had
been created by the alteration in the structure of society. Even if the
solutions which he proposed do not prove in every case to have been the best,
he undoubtedly foresaw what would be the chief occupation for the statesmen of
the future. In these reforms he had, however, little help from the Reichstag;
the Liberals were bitterly opposed, the Socialists sceptical and suspicious, the Catholics cool and unstable allies; during these years the
chronic quarrel between himself and Parliament broke out with renewed vigour. How bitterly did he deplore party spirit, the bane
of German life, which seemed each year to gain ground!
"It has,"
he said, "transferred itself to our modern public life and the
Parliaments; the Governments, indeed, stand together, but in the German
Reichstag I do not find that guardian of liberty for which I had hoped. Party
spirit has overrun us. This it is which I accuse before God and history, if the
great work of our people achieved between 1866 and 1870 fall into decay, and in
this House we destroy by the pen what has been created
by the sword."
In future years it
will perhaps be regarded as one of his chief claims that he refused to become a
party leader. He saved Germany from a serious danger to which almost every other country in Europe which has attempted to adopt
English institutions has fallen a victim—the sacrifice of national welfare to
the integrity and power of a Parliamentary fraction. His desire was a strong
and determined Government, zealously working for the benefit of all classes,
quick to see and foresee present and future evil; he regarded not the personal
wishes of individuals, but looked only in each matter
he undertook to its effect on the nation as a whole. "I will accept
help," he said, "wherever I may get it. I care not to what party any
man belongs. I have no intention of following a party policy; I used to do so
when I was a young and angry member of a party, but it is impossible for a
Prussian or German Minister." Though the Constitution had been granted, he
did not wish to surrender the oldest and best traditions of the Prussian
Monarchy; and even if the power of the King and Emperor was limited and checked
by two Parliaments it was still his duty, standing above all parties, to watch
over the country as a hundred years before his ancestors had done.
His power, however,
was checked by the Parliaments. Bismarck often sighed for a free hand; he
longed to be able to carry out his reforms complete and rounded as they lay
clear before him in his own brain; how often did he groan under all the delay,
the compromise, the surrender, which was imposed upon him when, conscious as he
was that he was only striving for the welfare of his country, he had to win
over not only the King, not only his colleagues in the Prussian Ministry, his
subordinates, who had much power to check and impede his actions, but, above
all, the Parliaments. It was inevitable that his relation to them should often
be one of conflict; it was their duty to submit to a searching criticism the
proposals of the Government and to amend or reject them, and let us confess that it was better they were there. The modifications they
introduced in the bills he proposed were often improvements; those they
rejected were not always wise. The drafting of Government bills was often badly
done; the first proposals for the Socialistic law, the original drafts of many
of his economic reforms, were all the better when they had been once rejected
and were again brought forward in a modified form. More than this, we must
confess that Bismarck did not possess that temperament which would make it wise
to entrust him with absolute dictatorial power in internal matters. He
attempted to apply to legislation habits he had learnt in diplomacy. And it is
curious to notice Bismarck's extreme caution in diplomacy, where he was a recognised master, and his rashness in legislation, where
the ground was often new to him. In foreign affairs a false move may easily be
withdrawn, a change of alliance quickly made; it often happens that speed is
more important than wisdom. In internal affairs it is different; there, delay
is in itself of value; moreover, false legislation
cannot be imposed with impunity, laws cannot be imposed and repealed.
Bismarck often
complained of the conduct of the Reichstag. There were in it two parties, the Socialists and the Centre, closely organised,
admirably disciplined, obedient to leaders who were in opposition by principle;
they looked on the Parliamentary campaign as a struggle for power, and they
maintained the struggle with a persistency and success which had not been
surpassed by any Parliamentary Opposition in any other country. Apart from them
the attitude of all the parties was normally that of moderate criticism
directed to the matter of the Government proposals. There were, of course,
often angry scenes; Bismarck himself did not spare his enemies, but we find no
events which shew violence beyond what is, if not legitimate, at least
inevitable in all Parliamentary assemblies. The main objects of the Government
were always attained; the military Budgets were always passed, though once not
until after a dissolution. In the contest with the Clerical party and the
Socialists the Government had the full support of a large majority. Even in the
hostile Reichstag of 1884, in which the Socialists, Clericals, and Progressives
together commanded a majority, a series of important laws were passed. Once,
indeed, the majority in opposition to the Government went beyond the limits of
reason and honour when they refused a vote of £1000
for an additional director in the Foreign Office. It was the expression of a
jealousy which had no justification in facts; at the time the German Foreign Office
was the best managed department in Europe; the labour imposed on the secretaries was excessive, and the nation could not help
contrasting this vote with the fact that shortly before a large number of the
members had voted that payments should be made to
themselves. The nation could not help asking whether it would not gain more
benefit from another £1000 a year expended on the Foreign Office than from
£50,000 a year for payment of members. Even this unfortunate action was
remedied a few months later, when the vote was passed in the same Parliament by
a majority of twenty.
Notwithstanding all
their internal differences and the extreme party spirit which often prevailed,
the Reichstag always shewed determination in defending its own privileges. More
than once Bismarck attacked them in the most tender points. At one time it was
on the privileges of members and their freedom from arrest; both during the
struggle with the Clericals and with the Socialists the claim was made to
arrest members during the session for political utterances. When Berlin was
subject to a state of siege, the President of the Police claimed the right of
expelling from the capital obnoxious Socialist members. On these occasions the
Government found itself confronted by the unanimous opposition of the whole
House. In 1884, Bismarck proposed that the meetings of the Reichstag should be biennial and the Budget voted for two years; the proposal
was supported on the reasonable grounds that thereby inconvenience and press of
work would be averted, which arose from the meeting of the Prussian and German
Parliaments every winter. Few votes, however, could be obtained for a
suggestion which seemed to cut away the most important privileges of
Parliament.
Another of the
great causes of friction between Bismarck and the Parliament arose from the
question as to freedom of debate. Both before 1866, and since that year, he
made several attempts to introduce laws that members should be to some extent
held responsible, and under certain circumstances be brought before a court of
law, in consequence of what they had said from their places in Parliament. This
was represented as an interference with freedom of speech,
and was bitterly resented. Bismarck, however, always professed, and I
think truly, that he did not wish to control the members in their opposition to
the Government, but to place some check on their personal attacks on
individuals. A letter to one of his colleagues, written in 1883, is
interesting:
"I have,"
he says, "long learned the difficulties which educated people, who have
been well brought up, have to overcome in order to meet the coarseness of our Parliamentary Klopfechter [pugilists] with the necessary amount of indifference, and to refuse them in
one's own consciousness the undeserved honour of
moral equality. The repeated and bitter struggles in which you have had to
fight alone will have strengthened you in your feeling of contempt for
opponents who are neither honourable enough nor
deserve sufficient respect to be able to injure you."
There was indeed a
serious evil arising from the want of the feeling of responsibility in a
Parliamentary assembly which had no great and honourable traditions. He attempted to meet it by strengthening the authority of the House
over its own members; the Chairman did not possess any power of punishing
breaches of decorum. Bismarck often contrasted this with the very great powers
over their own members possessed by the British Houses of Parliament. He drew
attention to the procedure by which, for instance, Mr. Plimsoll could be compelled to apologise for hasty words
spoken in a moment of passion. It is strange that neither the Prussian nor the
German Parliament consented to adopt rules which are really the necessary
complement for the privileges of Parliament.
The Germans were
much disappointed by the constant quarrels and disputes which were so frequent
in public life; they had hoped that with the unity of their country a new
period would begin; they found that, as before, the management of public
affairs was disfigured by constant personal enmities and the struggle of
parties. We must not, however, look on this as a bad sign; it is rather more
profitable to observe that the new institutions were not affected or weakened
by this friction. It was a good sign for the future that the new State held
together as firmly as any old-established monarchy, and that the most important
questions of policy could be discussed and decided without even raising any
point which might be a danger to the permanence of the Empire.
Bismarck himself
did much to put his relations with the Parliament on a new and better footing.
Acting according to his general principle, he felt that the first thing to be
done was to induce mutual confidence by unrestrained personal intercourse. The
fact that he himself was not a member of the Parliament deprived him of those
opportunities which an English Minister enjoys. He therefore instituted, in
1868, a Parliamentary reception. During the session, generally one day each
week, his house was opened to all members of the House. The invitations were
largely accepted, especially by the members of the National Liberal and
Conservative parties. Those who were opponents on principle, the Centre, the
Progressives, and the Socialists, generally stayed away. These receptions
became the most marked feature in the political life of the capital, and they
enabled many members to come under the personal charm of the Chancellor. What
an event was it in the life of the young and unknown Deputy from some obscure
provincial town, when he found himself sitting, perhaps, at the same table as
the Chancellor, drinking the beer which Bismarck had brought into honour at Berlin, and for which his house was celebrated,
and listening while, with complete freedom from all arrogance or pomposity, his
host talked as only he could!
The weakest side of
his administration lay in the readiness with which he had recourse to the
criminal law to defend himself against political adversaries. He was, indeed,
constantly subjected to attacks in the Press, which were often unjust and
sometimes unmeasured, but no man who takes part in public life is exempt from
calumny. He was himself never slow to attack his opponents, both personally in
the Parliament, and still more by the hired writers of the Press. None the
less, to defend himself from attacks, he too often brought his opponents into
the police court, and Bismarckbeleidigung became a
common offence. Even the editor of Kladderadatsch was
once imprisoned. He must be held personally responsible, for no action could be
instituted without his own signature to the charge. We see the same want of
generosity in the use which he made of attempts, or reputed attempts, at
assassination. In 1875, while he was at Kissingen, a young man shot at him; he
stated that he had been led to do so owing to the attacks made on the
Chancellor by the Catholic party. No attempt, however, was made to prove that
he had any accomplices; it was not even suggested that he was carrying out the
wishes of the party. It was one of those cases which will always occur in
political struggles, when a young and inexperienced man will be excited by
political speeches to actions which no one would foresee, and which would not
be the natural result of the words to which he had listened. Nevertheless,
Bismarck was not ashamed publicly in the Reichstag to taunt his opponents with
the action, and to declare that whether they would or not their party was
Kuhlmann's party; "he clings to your coat-tails," he said. A similar
event had happened a few years before, when a young man had been arrested on
the charge that he intended to assassinate the Chancellor. No evidence in
support of the charge was forthcoming, but the excuse was taken by the police
for searching the house of one of the Catholic leaders with whom the accused
had lived. No incriminating documents of any kind were found, but among the
private papers was the correspondence between the leaders in the party of the
Centre dealing with questions of party organisation and political tactics. The Government used these private papers for political purposes, and published one of them. The constant use of the
police in political warfare belonged, of course, to the system he had
inherited, but none the less it was to have been hoped that he would have been
strong enough to put it aside. The Government was now firmly established; it
could afford to be generous. Had he definitely cut himself off from these bad traditions he would have conferred on his country a
blessing scarcely less than all the others.
The opposition of
the parties in the Reichstag to his policy and person did not represent the
feelings of the country. As the years passed by and the new generation grew up,
the admiration for his past achievements and for his character only increased.
His seventieth birthday, which he celebrated in 1885, was made the occasion for
a great demonstration of regard, in which the whole nation joined. A national
subscription was opened and a present of two million marks was made to him.
More than half of this was devoted to repurchasing that part of the estate at Schoenhausen which had been sold when he was a young man.
The rest he devoted to forming an institution for the help of teachers in
higher schools. A few years before, the Emperor had
presented to him the Sachsen Wald, a large portion of the royal domains in the
Duchy of Lauenburg. He now purchased the neighbouring estate of Friedrichsruh, so that he had a third
country residence to which he could retire. It had a double advantage: its
proximity to the great forest in which he loved to wander, and
also to a railway, making it little more than an hour distant from
Berlin. He was able, therefore, at Friedrichsruh, to
continue his management of affairs more easily than he could at Varzin.
CHAPTER XVII.
RETIREMENT AND DEATH. 1887-1898.
|